The European Union has made significant progress to a more unified banking market but frictions remain between euro and non-euro countries. Without a coordinated approach to remaining issues in completing banking union, the gap could widen.
Completing banking union remains one of
the European Union’s policy priorities, notwithstanding the huge
economic impact of COVID-19. The rise in non-performing exposures (NPEs)
as support provided by EU governments peters out in the coming months
will be a major hit to bank balance sheets and could trigger renewed
ring fencing, or measures to protect assets, by home and host countries.
Significant progress towards a more
unified banking market has already been made. The single supervisory
mechanism (SSM) was agreed in 2013, and a bank resolution framework that
includes a resolution institution and fund, the Single Resolution Board
(SRB) and the Single Resolution Fund (SRF), has been put in place.
However, these reforms were concentrated
on the 19 EU countries that participate in the euro. The reforms thus
contribute to a steadily converging banking market in the euro area, but
this could create frictions with the banking markets of non-euro EU countries.
At the more granular level, sources of
divergence between euro-area countries and those outside could include
how and where banking groups can and should fund the loss-absorption
capacity of subsidiaries, and who should decide on how far to go in
separating the critical functions of banks. The banking union’s lack of a
unitary decision-making structure covering both the ins and outs could
exacerbate differences between the different parts of the EU’s banking
market. Without a unified approach that covers also those member states
outside the euro area, this will not be easily reversed.
Dealing with these challenges requires a well-designed and well-run system, but in Europe all is not well. Various factors inhibit the efficient functioning of supervision and resolution of financial institutions.
The gap in the internal market for banking services between euro-area
countries and those that have not yet adopted the euro could widen. Even
though the non-euro-area volumes are only a fraction of the banking
market in the euro area, re-introducing frictions to a smooth
functioning of markets is ill advised given the economic benefits of
well integrated markets especially in and for central and eastern
European countries.
Home-host issues in general are at the
core of the policy problems we continue to witness. Whilst still an
issue within banking union, the real problems that require significant
moves at the policy and political level are between ins and outs. Parent
banks consider themselves to be at the mercy of arbitrary policy
measures in the jurisdictions of their subsidiaries. National
authorities of subsidiaries in turn fear that they might be left to pick
up the mess once the parent bank has siphoned profits away from their
country.
The question is how and indeed if mutual
trust in the stability of framework conditions can be hardwired into the
system of a fully functioning internal market for banking services in
the EU. Indeed, lack of trust in (other people’s) national rules, and in
the willingness of parents to pick up the costs of resolution of
failing subsidiaries, are at the core of lack of progress in creating a
well-functioning internal market for banking.
Ultimately, the decisive question is who
pays the bill. This may depend on why a bill has to be paid: is it due
to failings of the national policy framework, of management or
governance problems of the banking group, or possibly due to exogenous
factors.
In a unitary jurisdiction such costs, to
the extent that they are not mitigated by bail-in procedures, are borne
by the taxpayer. A common backstop, or a similar construction, that
fulfils such functions is required in the EU in order to overcome
home-host issues. This is not in sight, and would also require the
European Commission and the supervisor to play a more ambitious role in
judging whether national policy frameworks are not detrimental to the
fiscal interests of a common backstop.
These are fairly well analysed issues
between ins and outs. Less noted are divergences stemming from the
issues covered by the Bank Recovery and Resolution Directive (BRRD,
2014/59/EU). This major legislative act was put in place in order to
lead to convergence over time on the resolvability or winding down of
credit institutions, and to deal with other features of the system (a Single Resolution Report summarises these issues).
Two issues risk making the banking market
of the 27 even more fragmented in the foreseeable future by driving a
further wedge between ins and outs, if not addressed carefully by
European policymakers.
As of 2021, BRRD II (Directive (EU)
2019/879) will introduce options for resolution bodies for bail-in
capital at the level of subsidiaries, and the SRB policies on
‘separability’ are about to be implemented.
Thus, the funding of loss-absorption
capacity and the issue of who decides (and how) on the issue of
separability of entities within a cross-border banking group should be
approached with the aim of leading to greater market convergence in the
EU instead of divergence.
In Europe there are two accepted models
for handling cross-border bank resolution planning for international
banking groups (codified in BRRD II): the single point of entry (SPE)
and multiple point of entry (MPE), to be adopted by the respective
resolution college.
One of the main distinctions is whether
the holding company alone issues Minimum Requirement for own funds and
Eligible Liabilities (MREL) type bonds (SPE: losses are passed up and
capital is passed down), or bail-in capital needs to be raised in each
separate jurisdiction (MPE: losses remain local, bailed-in investors
become new owners of a separate national entity).
The financing of adequate loss absorption
capacity in subsidiaries requires local MREL. However, markets in some
countries that joined the EU in 2004 and after lack well-developed
investor bases for locally issued subordinated debt. The greater the
share of local funding in the smaller EU national markets the more
easily an MPE approach can be made operational, as parent and wholesale
financing from abroad decline in importance.
To make things even more complicated
different national competent authorities (NCAs) reportedly favour
different strategies: Poland is apparently more inclined to MPE, whilst
Romania is usually mentioned as a proponent of SPE.
Whether SPE or MPE is better in any sense
is neither here nor there: the point is that different requirements on
such issues make cross-border banking disjointed and less efficient.
Thus, it should be either up to the banking group or a European
supervisor to determine which method a bank can or should apply. At
present it can be presumed that the European Banking Authority (EBA) or
the SRB would agree that it is up to the subsidiary (or its parent, as
the case may be) to decide autonomously on its funding strategy,
including the source of bail-in capital. Practice may differ, depending
on the approach of the respective NCA.
The BRRD also requires banking groups to
document the separability of parent and subsidiary in operational terms,
a logical prerequisite if one wants to ensure containment of local or
regional financial stress. Separation becomes easier with steadily
developing local markets.
However, the apparently mundane issue of
separability is in practice more problematic than one might think. Under
BRRD and SRM legislation, banks must provide information on their
separability, which was at the time mainly intended to cover ‘living
wills’ (ie questions of internal organisation, continuity planning and
the like).
There are quite obviously significant
costs of being inseparable, but also costs of being required to be
significantly separable. The more stringent the requirements imposed by
NCAs are, the more the traditional model of banking groups as a genuine
group is put into question. It seems logical that separability should be
well documented and approved by the SRB and/or the supervisory college,
taking due account of the role of the EBA. This implies that there need
not be a de-facto far-reaching separation of business activities.
Thus, the issue of whether the subsidiary
must be separable in operational terms, and demonstrably separable in
funding terms, is core to problems in resolution planning for
cross-border groups.
Without a coordinated and joint approach
to these issues, the banking markets of euro outs, especially in central
and eastern Europe, risk being less well integrated into the internal
market for banking services, with all associated costs to growth and
welfare.
Recommended citation:
Wieser, T. (2020) ‘Can the gap in the Europe’s internal market for banking services be bridged?’, Bruegel Blog, 7 December
© Bruegel
Key
Hover over the blue highlighted
text to view the acronym meaning
Hover
over these icons for more information
Comments:
No Comments for this Article