The G7 agreement on taxation of global corporations still needs formal approval from a wider set of countries, and there remain many details to be worked out for it to be effective. Nonetheless, it would not be farfetched to describe the deal as historic.
On June 5, the world’s leading economies announced an agreement
that will bolster their ability to raise taxes on global corporations.
The agreement still needs formal approval from a wider set of countries,
and there remain many details to be worked out for it to be effective.
Nonetheless, it would not be farfetched to describe the deal as
historic.
The G7 agreement has two planks. First, it
proposes a global minimum tax of 15% on the largest corporations.
Second, a portion of these corporations’ global profits will be clawed
back to countries where they do business, regardless of the location of
their physical headquarters.These objectives are as clear an indication
as any that hyper-globalization’s rules – under which countries must
compete to offer global corporations ever-sweeter deals – are being
re-written.
Until very recently, it was opposition by the United States
that stalled global tax harmonization. Now, by contrast, it was
President Joe Biden’s administration that pushed the deal.Since the race to the bottom in corporate taxation began in the 1980s, the average statutory rate has come down from nearly 50% to around 24%
in 2020. Many countries have generous loopholes and exemptions that
reduce the effective tax rate to single digits.
Even more damaging,
global corporations have been able to shift profits to pure tax havens
such as the British Virgin Islands, the Cayman Islands, or Bermuda,
without having to move any of their actual operations there. Estimates
by Gabriel Zucman of the University of California, Berkeley, reveal
that an inordinate share of US corporations’ foreign profits are booked
in such tax havens, where they employ only a few people.
Leaving
questions about administrative feasibility aside, the new agreement
might face two opposing objections. Tax-justice advocates will criticize
the global minimum of 15% as too low, while many developing countries
will decry the global minimum as an unwarranted restriction that will
impede their ability to attract investment. The deal struck by the G7
appears to reflect both sets of concerns: the low threshold could
assuage developing countries’ concerns, while the global apportionment
of profits will enable high-tax jurisdictions to recoup some of their
lost revenues.
Among developed countries, only Ireland, with a 12.5% statutory rate, falls below the proposed minimum. But there are small countries
such as Moldova (12%), Paraguay (10%), and Uzbekistan (7.5%) that have
set their rates particularly low to attract foreign investors, whom they
see as a source of quality jobs and advanced technologies. In
unhospitable investment environments, lower taxes are one of the few
immediate ways in which governments can compensate companies for the
many disadvantages they face. And effective tax rates in some Asian
countries, such as Singapore (where the statutory rate is 17% but lower rates apply to some businesses), may end up on the wrong side of the minimum as well.
The argument for
enforcing a common floor on corporate taxation is strongest when
countries have similar preferences and want to avoid a prisoner’s
dilemma in which their only reason to lower taxes is to prevent capital
from going elsewhere. This may apply to most developed countries, but
certainly not all, as the examples of Ireland, the Netherlands, and
Singapore indicate. But when countries greatly differ in terms of levels
of development and other characteristics, what is appropriate in one
can be an obstacle to growth in another.
The US and high-tax European
countries might complain about losing tax revenues when poorer
countries maintain lower rates. But there is nothing to prevent such
countries from taxing their home companies unilaterally at higher rates:
they can simply apply the tax to domestic companies’
global profits, apportioned by the share of revenues they derive from the domestic market. As Zucman has
argued, each country can do this on its own, without global harmonization or even coordination.That
is precisely what the second plank of the G7 agreement envisages
(although it goes only part of the way).
Under the agreement, the
largest multinational companies with profit margins of at least 10%
would have to allocate 20% of their global profits to countries where
they sell their products and services.The reason that the US prefers a
global minimum, in addition to national apportionment, is that it does
not want to put its corporations at a disadvantage relative to other
countries’ firms by taxing them at significantly higher rates. But this
competitive motive is no different from poor countries’ desire to
attract investment. If the US prevails and the latter lose out, it will
be because of relative power, not economic logic.The Biden
administration initially wanted the global minimum tax set at 21%. The
eventual compromise of 15% may be sufficiently low to minimize tensions
with poorer countries and to allow the latter to sign on. The balance
between global rules and national sovereignty may have been struck
appropriately in this instance.
But for countries
like the US, this comes at the cost of lower tax revenues, unless the
second plank of apportionment is strengthened. Ultimately, a global
regime that enhances the ability of individual countries to design and
administer their own tax systems, in light of their own needs and
preferences, is likely to prove more robust and durable than attempts at
international tax harmonization.
What is now clear is that countries
that operate as pure tax havens – interested merely in shifting paper
profits without bringing in new capital – have little to complain about.
They have been doing global corporations a great service by
facilitating tax avoidance, at considerable costs to other countries
treasuries. Global rules are fully justified to prevent such blatant
beggar-thy-neighbor action. The G7 agreement is an important step in the
right direction.
Project Syndicate
© Project Syndicate
Key
Hover over the blue highlighted
text to view the acronym meaning
Hover
over these icons for more information
Comments:
No Comments for this Article