The European Union’s proposed Digital Markets Act will attempt to control online gatekeepers by subjecting them to a wider range of upfront constraints
Digital market forces drive huge
efficiency gains. But they also create winner-take-all dynamics that
can, left unchecked, lead to monopolistic markets and hurt consumers in
the long-run. Slow-moving competition policy tools are ill-equipped to
fully address these digital concerns.
(1) The DMA was proposed alongside the
Digital Services Act (DSA) which targets illegal goods, services and
content, abuse of platforms, advertising and algorithmic transparency.
The DSA concerns most online businesses.
In December 2020 the European Commission
proposed the Digital Markets Act (DMA) to regulate the gatekeepers of
the digital world by imposing direct restrictions on the behaviour of
tech giants (1). While the Commission has not named any companies, it
has proposed criteria that are sure to catch Google, Facebook, Amazon,
Apple, Microsoft and SAP, among others.
This blog unpacks the different provisions of the DMA and explains why the Commission chose to regulate big tech.
What is a digital gatekeeper?
A gatekeeper is a company that acts as an
important nexus between two or more groups of users – say buyers and
sellers. When they attract a large share of users on one side of the
platform (say buyers) gatekeepers can become unavoidable tolls on routes
to certain markets or customers. Users on the other side of the
platform (say sellers) may have little choice but to use the
gatekeepers’ infrastructure.
The EU has thought in terms of ‘digital gatekeeper’ for as long as Google has existed.
In the DMA, it defines a gatekeeper as a platform that operates in one
(or more) of the digital world’s eight core services (including search,
social networking, advertising and marketplaces) in at least three EU
countries and:
- Has a significant impact on the internal market (defined
quantitatively as an annual turnover of €6.5 billion or a market
capitalisation of €65 billion);
- Serves as an important gateway for business users to reach end-users
(user base larger than 45 million monthly end-users and 10,000 business
users yearly); and
- Enjoys an entrenched and durable position or is likely to continue
to enjoy such a position (meets the first and second criteria over three
consecutive years).
A platform that meets these quantitative
thresholds is labelled a gatekeeper. However, the Commission would
retain the right to remove (or confer) ‘gatekeeper’ status by
qualitative assessment. The Commission would also be empowered to alter
the thresholds as technologies change, and to conduct market
investigations to look for new gatekeepers.
Why big tech is big
Digital hubs are a time drain. In December 2019 (pre-COVID-19), the average Italian
spent 45 hours a month on Facebook, and 24 hours on Google. The same
may be true for physical marketplaces and social venues, but online, the
hubs are controlled by only a handful of global players. British
internet users spend 40%
of their online time on sites owned by just two providers (Google and
Facebook). These same two providers are frequented by 96% and 87% of
British users each month. 58% of Germans book their holidays through just one site (Booking.com).
For a long time, policymakers were not
especially worried about high concentration in digital markets. They
assumed digital champions faced competition ‘for the market’, that is,
competition from outside players keen on becoming tomorrow’s winners.
After all, Facebook outcompeted MySpace. Google overtook AltaVista.
Nokia once looked unassailable.
But the competitive dynamics of the early
days of the internet no longer seem to apply. While the primacy of
AltaVista lasted one year (and Myspace three years), a decade
of that of Google and Facebook has now passed. The persistence of
today’s digital leaders has become concerning: have they found a way out
of the competitive race?
There are several explanations for the
unusual persistence of digital leadership. For one, digital markets
feature characteristics of ‘tipping markets’, or markets in which there
is room for only a few players. These characteristics are the
combination of:
- Consumer inertia (why bother shop for a new email provider when the current one works just fine?);
- Increasing returns to scale (recommendation algorithms become better with more users);
- Low marginal costs (it costs close to nothing to distribute one extra app);
- Strong direct and indirect network effects (the more users frequent a
social media site, the more attractive it becomes to other users and to
advertisers).
To illustrate, consider the market for
mobile operating systems (OS). OS with more end-users are naturally more
attractive to app developers than OS with fewer end-users. Developers
thus tend to prioritise the largest OS (an example of indirect network
effects). Over time, the gap in what larger and smaller OS can offer
grows. The large OS gather more user data which helps them improve the
quality of their recommendations. The small OS become even less
attractive, until they go bust and the winners take all. One of the
reasons Microsoft abandoned the mobile market in 2017 is that it could not attract enough app makers to its OS.
Masses of data, cheap machine learning technologies and the refining of ecosystem business models have
further entrenched leading positions, conferring incredible bargaining
power to set commercial conditions and terms unilaterally (eg to expel,
charge high fees, manipulate rankings and control reputations). Such
power leaves platform users vulnerable to abuse.
Online gatekeepers are a source of concern
Success is by no means illegal. But
practices that lock it in might well become unlawful. The DMA would
constrain gatekeepers’ behaviour while forcing them to proactively open
up to more competition. Those in breach of the rules face penalties of
up to 10% of their yearly turnover and repeat offenders face being
broken-up. The DMA addresses two problems: high barriers to entry and
anticompetitive practices by gatekeepers. The objective is to make
digital markets both contestable and fair for existing and future
rivals.
To illustrate, consider the DMA’s
prohibition on combining end-user data from different sources without
consent. Combining data from multiple sources can give gatekeepers a
significant advantage over smaller rivals. Indeed, data gleaned from one
source, say online searches, can be used to predict users’ preferences
in other market, say music streaming. A gatekeeper that knows the web
browsing history of a user is much better positioned to predict her
musical tastes than a data-poor rival. Restricting the combination of
data from multiple sources, therefore, restricts the ability of
gatekeepers to leverage their market power from one market to another to
the detriment of small players.
Other prominent rules include:
- No self-preferencing: a prohibition on ranking their own products over others;
- Data portability: an obligation to facilitate the portability of continuous and real-time data;
- No ‘spying’: a prohibition on gatekeepers on using the data of their business users to compete with them;
- Interoperability of ancillary services: an obligation to allow
third-party ancillary service providers (eg payment providers) to run on
their platforms;
- Open software: an obligation to permit third-party app stores and software to operate on their OS.
The proposal also includes a requirement
that gatekeepers inform the regulator of all mergers and acquisitions,
even when the target is too small to be subject to merger control. It
does not include any powers to intervene to block these mergers however
(unlike the equivalent UK proposal).
As with the definition of ‘gatekeeper’,
the DMA’s list of obligations is a balancing act between enforceability
and flexibility. Indeed, while seven rules apply equally to all
gatekeepers, the majority (eleven rules) will be tailored to each.
The practical consequences of unconstrained power
In the last few years, numerous studies (twenty-two of which are summarised here)
and antitrust investigations have suggested that some gatekeepers
adopted questionable practices from a competition standpoint (Table 1).
In setting the DMA list of obligations,
the Commission drew on the knowledge it acquired through the various
antitrust investigations: the DMA rulebook targets most of the unfair
practices listed in Table 1. Take the Amazon case for example. The
Commission suspects the e-retailer of gathering data on the activities
of third-party sellers in order to outcompete them. One DMA obligation –
for gatekeepers not to use the data of business users to compete with
them – would clearly addresses the problematic practice.....
more at Bruegel
© Bruegel
Key
Hover over the blue highlighted
text to view the acronym meaning
Hover
over these icons for more information
Comments:
No Comments for this Article