The European Commission has finally issued the proposed Digital Markets Act, its bid to complement antitrust intervention in digital markets with ex-ante regulation in the form of a set of obligations that platforms identified as “gatekeepers” should abide by.
This column argues that the current proposal makes good progress, but
lacks the translation tools to map the rules from the settings that
inspired them to other businesses that are deemed gatekeepers, that the
rules may not do enough to recognise the direct consumer harm that flows
from the exploitation of data and the extraction and appropriation of
consumer value, and that merger control remains a significant lacuna in
the Commission’s digital regime that will need to be addressed
separately. In contrast, the UK CMA proposals condition the rules on
business models and fold merger control into the digital regime.
The European Commission has finally issued the proposed Digital
Markets Act (DMA), its bid to complement antitrust intervention in
digital markets with ex-ante regulation in the form of a set of
obligations that platforms identified as “gatekeepers” should abide
by. The UK – having severed its links with Europe – simultaneously laid
out its own distinct approach to regulating digital markets, now taking
real shape after the statement of intentions in the 2019 Furman
report. All of this is happening, extraordinarily, in the very same
weeks that have seen five major complaints filed in the US against
Google and Facebook by the federal agencies and the state attorney
generals. And China has opened a major investigation of e-commerce giant
Alibaba.
While the final form of the EU DMA rules will change possibly
substantially in its journey through the European Parliament and
European capitals before final approval, there is a lot to consider
already. First, let’s say what this isn’t. Americans in particular,
looking at it from afar, may expect it to be something akin to common
carrier or public utility-style regulation. Not so – the regime is not
designed to regulate infrastructure monopolies, but rather to create
competition as well as to redistribute some rents. Second, the current
definition of “gatekeeper” is not nuanced, and so we expect it will be
updated and improved in the review process. Third, in our reading, the
list of Obligations seems to be a catalogue derived from past and
current antitrust cases involving the usual set of big tech platforms,
but lacks the translation tools to map a rule from the setting that
inspired it to other businesses that are deemed gatekeepers. Translating
these dicta into actionable rules that people and companies can
understand likely will require clearer organising principles around
business models. The UK is doing just this – the CMA proposed regulation
identifies the equivalent of a gatekeeper platform while at the same
time creating a set of rules designed for that specific business model.
Fourth, while “data” is mentioned multiple times in the Obligations, it
is unclear that the rules do enough to recognise the direct consumer
harm that flows from the exploitation of data and the extraction and
appropriation of consumer value, amplified by privacy concerns. Lastly,
while we understand there are legal reasons why the DMA could not
include merger reform, the effective regulation of digital platforms
requires powering up this essential tool. As the UK is folding its
merger control into its digital markets regime, and the US is making
undoing bad mergers a cornerstone of its antitrust cases against
Facebook and Google, there appears to be a significant lacuna in the EC
digital regime that needs to be addressed.
For Americans: What this isn't
The US’ “big awakening” on the use of antitrust to deal with digital
markets (Google and Facebook in particular) is much welcome and overdue.
To Europeans, the recent federal and state complaints have looked like
an extraordinary giant iceberg breaking free and finally on the move –
with a much broader scope and bolder agenda than anything Europe had set
out to do. While Europe has done good cases, zooming in on a particular
market and conduct (Google Shopping, Android), nothing has
been quite as far-reaching in ambition. “You cannot buy your way out of
competition” is the big underlying theme of the US complaints – a theme
that has broad reach, encompassing exclusivity agreements, special
deals with rivals to keep them out of a market, and multiple
acquisitions to buy out threats. It will take some time for the US
policy community to evaluate what they can expect to achieve with these
cases and on what timeline. In the future we expect to see digital
regulatory initiatives advance also in the US.
And because experimentation with different approaches will matter,
industry participants and policymakers in the US will benefit from
watching the European regulatory experiment unfold. It is important for
Americans to appreciate that the European DMA (European Commission 2020)
is not is a step to breakups (in classic European fashion,
these are briefly mentioned only as a last resort for repeat offenders)
or a common carrier/public utility style regulation. Its animating
principle is not so much to control the power of a monopoly
infrastructure (e.g. setting access terms), but much more to prohibit or
discourage conduct that has either the intent or effect of preventing
entry of a rival (or raising its cost) where entry would otherwise be possible. A second purpose is to enforce fairness,
a strong pillar of the European ordoliberal tradition, by prohibiting
conduct that exploits and weakens counterparties that depend on the
platform. Removing obstacles to entry, and fairness in the relationship
with dependants, are the two goals of the law. Its method is
“pro-competitive regulations” that seek to tame market power by enabling
new competitors, rather than choosing price or quality levels.1
Note that this is quite different from a sector-specific regulator
who might approve particular prices or approve certain product
characteristics. US observers tend to associate the word “regulation”
with this type of market intervention. The EC law is designed to operate
much more strongly on the dimension of barriers to entry and to
competition in the expectation that, if entry barriers are lowered, more
competition can create a competitive price or quality (though consumer
protection is also needed, which the parallel Digital Services Act –
issued simultaneously to the DMA – is intended to take up).
The European Commission approach: Needs a translation key, and some organising principles
The DMA envisages a two-step process in which the “provider of a core platform service”2 first self-designates as a “gatekeeper”, and then adheres to list of obligations that apply to all gatekeepers.
The criteria for the designation of a gatekeeper are quantitative
(annual EEA turnover above €6.5 billion in the last three years,
average market capitalisation or equivalent fair market value above €65
billion in the last year, active in at least three Member States, over
45 million monthly active end users in the Union and over 10,000 yearly
active business users in the last year). Back-of-the-envelope
calculations suggest that these criteria will capture not only
(obviously) the core businesses of the largest players (GAFAM), but
perhaps also a few others. Oracle and SAP, for instance, would appear to
meet the thresholds, as would AWS and Microsoft Azure. Conversely
Twitter, AirBnB, Bing, Linkedin, Xbox Netflix, Zoom and Expedia do not
appear to meet the thresholds at present, and Bookings.com, Spotify,
Uber, Bytedance/TikTok, Salesforce, Google Cloud and IBM Cloud appear to
meet some but not others at this point.3
For those that do not meet the quantitative criteria, there is a
long-winded alternative method of designation via a “market
investigation” – a new tool which, however, will require time to get
going and to run, and may not survive the review process in its current
form.4 The designation of gatekeepers mainly through
quantitative rules is clearly intended to leave no room for the
imagination – it will curb shenanigans and flannelling by companies
trying to argue against all common sense, and speed up the process of
designation. On the other hand, a more principled approach will be
needed for platforms that fall below the hard thresholds but may still
be capable of conduct the law wishes to proscribe.
There are then two sets of “obligations” laid out for gatekeepers: a
shorter list of obligations that apply without qualification, and a
longer list of obligations “susceptible of being further specified” –
the latter more tentative and “for discussion”, the former a definitive
list of proscribed conducts (i.e. “thou shall not”).
Identifying conducts that are not acceptable in general is
important and right, but these lists are a curious game of
charades. With experience and familiarity with past, current and
pipeline EC antitrust cases, one can just about assign each entry to a
particular company and its issue. We attempt to do this in the table
below. But this mapping is not obvious, because the writers have
generalised each case away from its specific setting in order to apply a
rule across the board. And then, when the mapping is finished, it is
clear that some rules really are specific to one – or perhaps two –
platforms, but unclear how they might or should apply to others, both
within and outside the traditional GAFA list. So how can these lists be
made operational? Some organising principles around business models
would have been more useful, even if one does not want to get too
“close and personal” and name individual companies. A fixed set of rules
– covering all kinds of business models – applying to any platform that
is designated a gatekeeper is the contrary of “flexible”. What is more,
the separation between the designation of a gatekeeper first, and the
application of the obligation second, is artificial because it is
through the evaluation of conduct and its impact that an agency would
identify a gatekeeper and understand what particular rules would
ameliorate the problems that have been identified. As discussed further
below, the UK seems to be taking this combined approach.
The gatekeeper role cannot be independent of business models
Intuitively, we think of a gatekeeper as an intermediary who
essentially controls access to critical constituencies on either side of
a platform that cannot be reached otherwise, and as a result can engage
in conduct and impose rules that counterparties cannot avoid. Susan Athey proposes a similar definition: “A platform acts as a gatekeeper when it aggregates a meaningfully large group of participants that are not reachable elsewhere”
(Athey 2020). The key is that the way in which gatekeeping power can
materialise is distinct across business models (and platforms are often
conglomerates operating several related businesses models; for example,
Amazon Marketplace is distinct from AWS, Google’s various individual
businesses – operating systems, search, placing of display ads – are all
different, and so on). The designation of gatekeeper applies not to the
whole firm, but to one business within the conglomerate.
The need to recognise business models explicitly in designing rules
for tech is now well established (Caffarra 2019, Athey 2020, Caffarra et
al. 2020). The DMA makes only a fleeting reference to business models
(four times in the whole document, and to no particular purpose), but in
practice there are big differences in economic properties and incentives
across these business models. Compare three rough groups: ad-funded
digital platforms (Google, Facebook, Bing, Pinterest, Twitter,
Snapchat), transaction or matchmaking platforms that are marketplaces
and exchanges (Uber, Airbnb, Amazon, DoubleClick), and OS ecosystem
platforms (i.e. operating systems and app stores such as iOS, Appstore,
Android, Google Play Store, Microsoft Windows, AWS, Microsoft Azure
etc.). These business models differ in systematic ways in terms of (a)
the type of economies of scale they rely on (data scale, R&D costs); (b) the type and direction of network effects (direct/indirect, one/both directions); (c) the potential for multihoming (on
one or both sides), and (as emphasised again by Athey); and (d) the
potential for disintermediation, either by someone else “introducing a
different layer” intermediating two sides of the platform (e.g. end
users and business users) or finding a way for two sides to connect to
each other directly.
These distinctions matter because they mean the entry strategies of competitors will differ, and therefore defensive strategies will also differ. They also matter for the definition of a gatekeeper. Because a gatekeeper must be a business that controls access to a large enough group of users to affect entry and competition, key to the designation of a gatekeeper is whether there are obstacles to multihoming, and whether users cannot directly bypass the platform.
Obstacles to multihoming and disintermediation could be in part
inherent to the service (transaction costs, technical barriers), but
could also be induced by the conduct of the platform. At the stage of
designating a gatekeeper, this distinction does not matter. If there is a
large enough user base that entry depends on, including upstream and
downstream, and there is limited ability to multihome and no real
possibility for bypassing the platform, then the platform business will
be deemed to have “gatekeeper power”. However, the analysis of
disintermediation and multihoming possibilities differs between three
main categories of business models: ad-funded businesses,
transaction/match-making businesses, and operating systems/app stores. ...
more at Vox
© VoxEU.org
Key
Hover over the blue highlighted
text to view the acronym meaning
Hover
over these icons for more information
Comments:
No Comments for this Article