As the digital transformation in banking has gathered pace, so have cyber risks to financial stability. The prevalence of cyber attacks is particularly pronounced in the financial system
: Data from the Carnegie Endowment for International
Peace indicates that the number of cyber attacks on financial
institutions is increasing four-fold, year-on-year (Mauer and Nelson,
2020). Together, these trends pose a new challenge for financial sector
participants. Despite the growing interest in cyber risk, there is
currently no model that links cyber attacks to bank and investor
behaviour. This policy brief summarises recent analysis (Anand, et al.,
2022) clarifying how cyber attacks can engender financial instability.
"Cyber
security is a public good… the social benefit conveyed by a well
functioning and resilient financial system… requires a higher level of
investment in cyber security than what individual firms would like to do
on their own. In addition, many individual firms rely on shared
services.... an individual firm may rely on others in the shared network
to make investments to increase the security of the network, but if
every firm thinks this way, there will be underinvestment in security." − Loretta J. Mester, Reserve Bank of Cleveland, 21 November 2019.
Cybersecurity as a public good
Our analytical framework builds on the
premise that banks use shared digital services provided by third-party
vendors who offer scale-efficiencies. Examples include data warehousing,
runtime services, and operating systems that facilitate both customer
online banking services and the bank’s back-end operations. Adoption of
these services by financial institutions has been accelerating over the
past few years (Harmon, 2020). Services are provided by just a handful
of companies. A survey by Gartner (2019) estimates that Amazon,
Microsoft, Alibaba, Google, and IBM account for 77% of the market.
While cost saving, shared services,
which we refer to as “platforms”, create cybersecurity dependencies –
one bank’s access can become the ‘back door’ through which attackers
impact others. By gaining access to a bank’s systems, attackers can
deploy malicious code to exploit vulnerabilities in the platform – which
are often unknown even to the vendor (Perlroth, 2021) – and cause
outages. The Stuxnet malicious code that spread via Microsoft Windows
and targeted industrial control systems is an example of an attack that
exploited several zero-day vulnerabilities (McDonald et al., 2013).
Since remedial actions against
vulnerabilities are not always available, banks must, therefore, invest
in cybersecurity to monitor and repel unauthorised intrusions into their
systems. Investing in cybersecurity allows a bank to protect both
itself and others on the platform. Cybersecurity thus has the hallmarks
of a weakest-link public good (Hirshleifer, 1983; Cornes, 1993). Just as
in times of flood, the sea penetrates the sector where citizens have
constructed the lowest dike, the cybersecurity of the financial system
depends on the bank with the lowest level of protection. As such, we can
picture the “security blanket” over the platform as a circular region
with banks situated along the perimeter. Each bank is responsible for
maintaining security along its portion of the perimeter. But an attacker
who breaches the section of the perimeter guarded by one bank can
disrupt the platform and adversely impact all banks. The weakest-link
formulation implies that investment in cybersecurity generates positive
externalities for all banks.
Cyber attacks
We argue that cyber attacks may be
characterised by three factors. First, there is the intensity with which
attackers try to breach the cybersecurity defences and causing the
platform to suffer an outage. Uncertainty over the intensity of an
attack reflects uncertainty about the identity of the attacker - this
attribution problem is a distinguishing feature of cyber attacks
(Hayden, 2011). For example, state-sponsored attackers have considerable
resources to launch more sophisticated attacks that are more likely to
be successful than attacks by typical cyber-criminals.
Second, following a successful intrusion
and the deployment of malicious code, the shared services may suffer
temporary outages that disrupt operations for all banks. For example,
the recent distributed denial of service (DDoS) attack on the New
Zealand Stock Exchange prevented the posting of market announcements and
led to trading suspensions over several days (Tarabay, 2021). During
these outages, banks are unable to access or manage some proportion of
their key functions.
Third, even after the attack has been
repelled, there may be longer-lasting damage. These include the loss of
secret information pivotal to the bank’s role as a financial
intermediary (Dang et al., 2017), losses incurred from paying ransom
demands, and even physical damage to critical systems. Bouveret (2018)
estimates that the annual average loss to banks from cyber attacks
amounts to some US$100 billion, or 9% of banks’ net income globally.
Bank illiquidity and insolvency conditions
Platform outages can impair a bank’s
ability to manage its assets and, thereby, service its debts in a timely
manner. In particular, if the outage is sufficiently large, relative to
the mass of debt holders who choose to withdraw, this can render the
bank illiquid but solvent. The decisions of debt holders to withdraw
are, in turn, driven by their concerns over the bank’s ability to pay.
In our model, we parametrise these concerns by the degree of rollover
risk.
Cyber attacks can also lead to banks
suffering financial losses. The credit downgrading in 2019 of the
Maltese bank, Valletta PLC, following a cyber attack highlights the
risks to bank insolvency (S&P Global Market Intelligence, 2019). If
the losses are large, they can lead to banks failing due to insolvency.
Figure 1 depicts how the insolvency and
illiquidity conditions of a bank − following a successful cyber attack −
are related. While the insolvency condition only depends on the
severity of the outage shock, the insolvency condition depends on both
the outage shock and mass of debt holders who withdraw. Importantly,
there is a critical mass of withdrawals, denoted γ, at which the two conditions intersect. Whenever withdrawals are less than γ,
then bank failure is primarily driven by insolvent. While, when the
mass of withdrawals is greater than , concerns over illiquidity are the
overarching reason for the bank to fail, even though it may be solvent...
more at SUERF
© SUERF
Key
Hover over the blue highlighted
text to view the acronym meaning
Hover
over these icons for more information
Comments:
No Comments for this Article