A guide through the swift evolution in the concept of digital money since early 2009, when Bitcoin was launched with the project, still not implemented, to replace legal tender. Stablecoins, have emerged more recently, and aim to remedy the shortcomings in the first generation of crypto-assets.
However, they carry many risks.
Meanwhile, central banks are considering whether to launch a digital
currency and are in some cases preparing for it.
In order to guide the reader through
the swift evolution in the concept of digital money since early 2009,
three stages are distinguished. In the first one, which started in early
2009, the launch of Bitcoin triggers a blossoming of crypto-assets in
its wake. Tether, launched in 2014, ushered in the stage of stablecoins.
The third stage is starting, with central banks considering whether to
launch a central bank digital currency (CBDC) and is some cases
preparing for it.
The table below summarises the main potential benefits and risks of crypto-assets, also drawing on Pfister (2020a).
Table: Main potential benefits and risks of crypto-assets
|
“First generation” crypto-assets
|
Stablecoins
|
Central bank digital currency
|
Bitcoin and similar
|
Issued in ICOs
|
Tether and similar
|
Global stablecoins
|
Wholesale
|
Retail
|
Benefits
|
Micro
|
New technology Speculation Pseudonymity International fund transfers
|
Speculation Financing of the economy
|
Protection against volatility of “first generation” crypto-assets with similar benefits (except speculation)
|
Perfectly safe and liquid instrument, permanently at par with legal tender
|
End-to-end transactions in crypto-assets
|
Complement to banknotes
|
Macro
|
Insignificant due to small size
|
?
|
Internationalisation of currency Stimulus to financial and payments innovation
|
Possibility to have real-time money market and monetary policy
|
Financial inclusion Link between central bank and public More efficient monetary policy if remuneration of CBDC linked to policy rate
|
Risks
|
Micro
|
Loss of value Hacking of wallets and platforms
|
Loss of value Scams if not regulated
|
Imperfect stability Fees/Low yield Lack of transparency
|
Fees? Low yield Transparency? Insufficient scalability/Interoperability Cyber risks
|
Insufficient scalabilty/Interoperability Cyber risks Single point of failure
|
Macro
|
Financing of illegal activities
|
Wholesale: Fragmentation of liquidity + Concentration of risks
Retail (in user countries): Loss of monetary policy efficiency + Disintermediation
|
Economic damage and reputation loss for central bank if micro-risk(s) materialise(s)
|
?
|
Less efficient monetary policy if remuneration of CBDC not linked to policy rate Bank disintermediation Runs facilitated
|
First stage: Crypto-assets in search of a myth
By early-September 2020, there were more
than 6,700 crypto-assets, with a total capitalisation of around EUR 268
billion (source: CoinMarketCap). However, Bitcoin accounted for close
to 59% of this total, compared with some 12% for Ethereum, slightly over
4% for Tether, and around 4% for Ripple. For this reason, and because
from the outset it aimed to play a monetary role (Nakamoto, 2008), the
focus here is on Bitcoin.
The three main characteristics of Bitcoin, also shared by many of the other crypto-assets, are as follows:
- It combines a public key with a private
key, which defines the asset in the absence of an issuer and guarantees
user anonymity. This lack of an issuer is what most distinguishes
Bitcoin from legal tender, be it fiduciary money or bank deposits.
- It relies on distributed ledger
technology (DLT), which makes the scheme more resilient and enables the
decentralised confirmation of transactions. However, for many
crypto‑assets, such as Ripple, stablecoins (see below) or assets issued
via initial coin offerings (ICOs; see below), transaction confirmation
is not decentralised.
- It systematically uses cryptography.
Bitcoin and the other first-generation
crypto-assets are essentially used for three purposes: speculative
investments; carrying out payment transactions under a pseudonym, which
helps to protect privacy but also facilitates the financing of illicit
activities; and transfers of funds abroad.
Overall, Bitcoin only very partially
fulfils the three functions of money. It is not a unit of account (it is
rarely if ever used to price goods and services). Nor is it a payment
instrument (very few purchases of goods and services are settled in
bitcoins), or a store of value (its exchange rate against other
currencies, and hence its value in terms of goods and services, is too
volatile).
While the idea that Bitcoin or other
crypto-assets might become a decentralised fiduciary currency is thus a
myth, the use of the underlying technology (DLT or blockchain) to issue
financial assets in the form of tokens appears more promising. To date,
two possible extensions of the use of DLT have emerged:
- The first is ICOs. These operations are
used for project financing, and consist in the issuance of tokens on a
blockchain in exchange for crypto-assets. Holders of the tokens are
given access to services on the issuing blockchain (utility tokens), or
may instead be remunerated, making the tokens similar to marketable
securities (security tokens). The presence of an issuer is what
distinguishes tokens from other first-generation crypto-assets. In 2018,
more than 1,000 ICOs were carried out, raising in excess of EUR 21
billion. However, the number of ICOs has declined since the second
quarter of 2018, following the sharp drop in the price of Bitcoin.
- The second possible use is the issuance of stablecoins.
Second stage: Stablecoins as a desire to reconcile crypto-assets with legal tender
Stablecoins first emerged in 2014. They
are designed to maintain a stable price vis-à-vis a benchmark, which is
most often the US dollar. Offering users the benefit of a stable
environment while enabling them to remain in the “crypto universe”,
stablecoins seem to offer “a brave new world” (Melachrinos and Pfister,
2020). Nonetheless, as at early-September 2020, the Stelareum website
lists only nine stablecoins for a total market capitalisation of around
EUR 14 billion or just over 5% of the capitalisation of all
crypto-assets. Moreover, Tether (USDT), a stablecoin referenced on the
dollar, accounts for more than four-fifths of the total amount.
Stablecoins in fact have a number of disadvantages (Melachrinos and Pfister, 2020):
- They are not perfectly stable vis-à-vis their benchmark.
- The fees on stablecoins are high.
- The current low level of interest rates means there are limited returns on projects backed by most major currencies.
- There is a lack of transparency notably because the reserves backing
them are often held outside the blockchain (off‑chain), and because the
claims users have on the assets held in the reserve are unclear.
At present, therefore, despite its
differences vis-à-vis first-generation crypto-assets, the market for
stablecoins is merely an appendix to that of other crypto-assets,
starting with Bitcoin. However, this status of stablecoins could change
with the arrival of global stablecoins (GSCs) issued by very large
players. The problem is that this would also potentially give the
projects a systemic footprint (G7, 2019).
Two main categories of GSCs (wholesale and retail) can be distinguished (Melachrinos and Pfister, 2020):
- Wholesale stablecoins are designed for
large-value transactions and aim at financial institutions and large
corporations. Two main projects stand out in this category: the USC
project and JPM Coin.
- Retail stablecoins are designed for
mass transactions. Among retail stablecoin projects, the most famous is
Libra, made public in June 2019 with the publication of the first White
Paper on Libra2.
Its different denominations would be backed by a legal currency or by a
basket including only stable currencies. Libra would be accessible to
Facebook account holders.
More than the historical crypto-assets,
GSCs could encourage the greater use of blockchain technology to reduce
frictions in cross-border payments and contribute to financial inclusion
in emerging countries. These projects nonetheless pose significant
risks to monetary policy and financial stability, many of which are akin
to those caused by dollarization:
- Regarding monetary policy, if
stablecoins backed by a currency other than the national legal tender of
the user country crowded the latter out, then any changes in the legal
tender interest rate would have less of an impact on domestic demand.
This risk would be particularly acute in emerging and developing
economies. An extreme case would be if a stablecoin became very widely
used and then was depegged from its reference currency and instead
pegged to itself, meaning it could set its own issuance terms.
- In the case of financial stability,
wholesale GSCs carry a residual credit risk, as the issuer might
default. They could also lead to a fragmentation of liquidity or,
conversely, to a concentration of risks in the event a single player
dominated the market. Retail GSCs could lead to a structural decline in
the resources of banks in user countries whose currency is not used by
the GSC if customers substituted the GSC for legal tender.
Third stage: Central bank digital currencies for digitized economies?
Should central banks also offer their
own digital payment instruments, in addition to banknotes, which are
physical, and to the reserves banks hold on accounts with them, which
have long been digitized, as they are already considering, notably in
China (Pfister, 2020a)?
A prerequisite for issuing a CBDC would
be that it is especially resilient, thus non-vulnerable to
cyber-attacks, as it would offer a “single point of failure” and a
successful attack would put the economy at risk, also damaging the
reputation of the central bank.
The reasons for issuing a CBDC may differ depending on the country:
- In developing and emerging economies,
the main concern is to promote financial inclusion. A retail CBDC could
also help reduce the cost of cash and the size of the informal economy.
- In developed economies, a wholesale
CBDC may foster financial innovation by enabling the use of blockchain
technology in end-to-end transactions. In countries such as Sweden,
where banknote usage is declining, a retail CBDC would offer a way of
maintaining a direct link of the central bank with the public. For both
retail and wholesale CBDCs, the desire to internationalise the currency
may also play a role.
How could the distribution of a CBDC be organised?
- In the case of a wholesale CBDC, DLT
could be used. However, a number of issues would need to be resolved,
such as the interoperability of blockchains accepting the CBDC.
- In the case of a retail CBDC, a central
bank electronic currency that did not require the use of a blockchain
may suffice. However, a blockchain would allow integrating smart
contracts (i.e. contracts that self-execute automatically when certain
predefined events occur). Having recourse to payment service providers,
which have experience in relationship with clientele, would facilitate
the distribution of CBDC.
Whatever the case, the issuance of a CBDC would raise a number of practical questions:
- Do the statutes of the central bank authorise it to issue a CBDC?
- Should the CBDC have legal tender status?
- How respond to the public’s desire for anonymity while preventing associated risks?
- Should non-residents be authorised to
hold the CBDC and, if not, what means would the central bank have to
prevent them from doing so?
- Should the CBDC model be token‑based or
account‑based? In the case of a retail CBDC, a token-based model would
be similar to that currently used for banknotes, prepaid cards and meal
vouchers. With an account-based model, financial intermediaries would
keep CBDC accounts for their customers.
Above all, how would a CBDC affect the core missions of a central bank?
- With regard to monetary policy, a
non-interest-bearing retail CBDC could put a “hard” zero floor on
short-term but also to long-term interest rates as expectations for
short-term interest rates would not be able to go below zero.
Conversely, if the retail CBDC were interest bearing and the
remuneration linked to the policy rate, it could reinforce the
transmission of monetary policy, as changes in the policy rate would
more directly affect bank deposit rates.
- In terms of financial stability, aside
from putting pressure on bank deposit rates, a retail CBDC could foster
disintermediation by substituting for bank deposits. However, banks
currently hold substantial liquidity surpluses resulting from central
bank asset purchases, which they could convert into CBDC. The issuance
of a CBDC could also facilitate flights to central bank money during
financial crises.
Despite these difficult questions,
central banks representing a fifth of the world’s population say they
are likely to issue the first CBDCs in the next few years (Boar et al., 2020).
References
Boar C., Holden H., Wadsworth A. (2020),
“Impending arrival – a sequel to the survey on central bank digital
currency”, BIS Papers, 107, January, https://www.bis.org/publ/bppdf/bispap107.pdf.
G7 Working Group on Stablecoins (2019), Investigating the impact of global stablecoins, Committee on Payments and Market Infrastructures, Bank for International Settlements, October, https://www.bis.org/cpmi/publ/d187.htm.
Melachrinos A., Pfister C. (2020), “Stablecoins: A brave new world?”, Working papers, No. 757, Banque de France, June, https://publications.banque-france.fr/en/stablecoins-brave-new-world.
Nakamoto S. (2008), “Bitcoin A peer-to peer electronic cash system”, https://bitcoin.org/bitcoin.pdf.
Pfister C. (2020a), “Central Bank Digital Currency: A Primer”, SUERF Policy Note 143, https://www.suerf.org/docx/f_a43fc3d27915b373b163da088684d4a9_10947_suerf.pdf.
Pfister C. (2020b), “Digital currencies: from myth to innovative projects”, Banque de France Bulletin, 230(1), 1-9, https://www.banque-france.fr/sites/default/files/medias/documents/bdf-230-1_digital-currencies_en.pdf.
About the author
Christian Pfister is a
senior consultant for digital currencies. He was before Deputy Director
General for Economics and International of the Banque de France
(2011-2013), Deputy Director General for Statistics (2013-2018) and
Advisor to the Governor (2019). He teaches at Sciences Po (Financial
Stability, with Françoise Drumetz) and Paris 1 Panthéon-Sorbonne
(Cryptocurrencies and Monetary Economics, with Lionel Potier and Mariana
Rojas-Breu). |
SUERF
© SUERF
Key
Hover over the blue highlighted
text to view the acronym meaning
Hover
over these icons for more information
Comments:
No Comments for this Article