Central bank digital currencies (CBDCs) offer in digital form the unique advantages of central bank money: settlement finality, liquidity and integrity. They are an advanced representation of money for the digital economy.
- Digital money should be designed with the
public interest in mind. Like the latest generation of instant retail
payment systems, retail CBDCs could ensure open payment platforms and a
competitive level playing field that is conducive to innovation.
- The ultimate benefits of adopting a new
payment technology will depend on the competitive structure of the
underlying payment system and data governance arrangements. The same
technology that can encourage a virtuous circle of greater access, lower
costs and better services might equally induce a vicious circle of data
silos, market power and anti-competitive practices. CBDCs and open
platforms are the most conducive to a virtuous circle.
- CBDCs built on digital identification
could improve cross-border payments, and limit the risks of currency
substitution. Multi-CBDC arrangements could surmount the hurdles of
sharing digital IDs across borders, but will require international
cooperation.
Introduction
Digital innovation has wrought far-reaching changes in all sectors of
the economy. Alongside a broader trend towards greater digitalisation, a
wave of innovation in consumer payments has placed money and payment
services at the vanguard of this development. An essential by-product of
the digital economy is the huge volume of personal data that are
collected and processed as an input into business activity. This raises
issues of data governance, consumer protection and anti-competitive
practices arising from data silos.
This chapter examines how central bank digital currencies (CBDCs) can
contribute to an open, safe and competitive monetary system that
supports innovation and serves the public interest. CBDCs are a form of
digital money, denominated in the national unit of account, which is a
direct liability of the central bank.1
CBDCs can be designed for use either among financial intermediaries
only (ie wholesale CBDCs), or by the wider economy (ie retail CBDCs).
The chapter sets out the unique features of CBDCs, asking what their
issuance would mean for users, financial intermediaries, central banks
and the international monetary system. It presents the design choices
and the associated implications for data governance and privacy in the
digital economy. The chapter also outlines how CBDCs compare with the
latest generation of retail fast payment systems (FPS, see glossary).2
To set the stage, the first section discusses the public interest
case for digital money. The second section lays out the unique
properties of CBDCs as an advanced representation of central bank money,
focusing on their role as a means of payment and comparing them with
cash and the latest generation of retail FPS. The third section
discusses the appropriate division of labour between the central bank
and the private sector in payments and financial intermediation, and the
associated CBDC design considerations. The fourth section explores the
principles behind design choices on digital identification and user
privacy. The fifth section discusses the international dimension of
CBDCs, including the opportunities for improving cross-border payments
and the role of international cooperation.
Money in the digital era
Throughout the long arc of history, money and its institutional
foundations have evolved in parallel with the technology available. Many
recent payment innovations have built on improvements to underlying
infrastructures that have been many years in the making. Central banks
around the world have instituted real-time gross settlement (RTGS)
systems over the past decades. A growing number of jurisdictions (over
55 at the time of writing)3
have introduced retail FPS, which allow instant settlement of payments
between households and businesses around the clock. FPS also support a
vibrant ecosystem of private bank and non-bank payment service providers
(PSPs, see glossary).
Examples of FPS include TIPS in the euro area, the Unified Payments
Interface (UPI) in India, PIX in Brazil, CoDi in Mexico and the FedNow
proposal in the United States, among many others. These developments
show how innovation can thrive on the basis of sound money provided by
central banks.
Yet further-reaching changes to the existing monetary system are
burgeoning. Demands on retail payments are changing, with fewer cash
transactions and a shift towards digital payments, in particular since
the start of the Covid-19 pandemic (Graph III 1,
left-hand and centre panels). In addition to incremental improvements,
many central banks are actively engaged in work on CBDCs as an advanced
representation of central bank money for the digital economy. CBDCs may
give further impetus to innovations that promote the efficiency,
convenience and safety of the payment system. While CBDC projects and
pilots have been under way since 2014, efforts have recently shifted
into higher gear (Graph III.1, right-hand panel).
The overriding criterion when evaluating a change to something as
central as the monetary system should be whether it serves the public
interest. Here, the public interest should be taken broadly to encompass
not only the economic benefits flowing from a competitive market
structure, but also the quality of governance arrangements and basic
rights, such as the right to data privacy.
It is in this context that the exploration of CBDCs provides an
opportunity to review and reaffirm the public interest case for digital
money. The monetary system is a public good that permeates people's
everyday lives and underpins the economy. Technological development in
money and payments could bring wide benefits, but the ultimate
consequences for the well-being of individuals in society depend on the
market structure and governance arrangements that underpin it. The same
technology could encourage either a virtuous circle of equal access,
greater competition and innovation, or it could foment a vicious circle
of entrenched market power and data concentration. The outcome will
depend on the rules governing the payment system and whether these will
result in open payment platforms and a competitive level playing field.
DC projects are moving ahead" border="0">
Central bank interest in CBDCs comes at a critical time. Several
recent developments have placed a number of potential innovations
involving digital currencies high on the agenda. The first of these is
the growing attention received by Bitcoin and other cryptocurrencies;
the second is the debate on stablecoins; and the third is the entry of
large technology firms (big techs) into payment services and financial
services more generally.
By now, it is clear that cryptocurrencies are speculative assets
rather than money, and in many cases are used to facilitate money
laundering, ransomware attacks and other financial crimes.4 Bitcoin in particular has few redeeming public interest attributes when also considering its wasteful energy footprint.5
Stablecoins attempt to import credibility by being backed by real
currencies. As such, these are only as good as the governance behind the
promise of the backing.6
They also have the potential to fragment the liquidity of the monetary
system and detract from the role of money as a coordination device. In
any case, to the extent that the purported backing involves conventional
money, stablecoins are ultimately only an appendage to the conventional
monetary system and not a game changer.
Perhaps the most significant recent development has been the entry of
big techs into financial services. Their business model rests on the
direct interactions of users, as well as the data that are an essential
by-product of these interactions. As big techs make inroads into
financial services, the user data in their existing businesses in
e-commerce, messaging, social media or search give them a competitive
edge through strong network effects. The more users flock to a
particular platform, the more attractive it is for a new user to join
that same network, leading to a "data-network-activities" or "DNA" loop
(see glossary). ...
more at BIS
© BIS - Bank for International Settlements
Key
Hover over the blue highlighted
text to view the acronym meaning
Hover
over these icons for more information
Comments:
No Comments for this Article