Central banks are rushing to pilot their own digital currencies. These may sound exciting. But they may offer users few compelling benefits they do not already enjoy.
Consumers are abandoning cash in favour of digital payments – a
long-term trend that rapidly accelerated during the pandemic. Central
banks are fretting
about the consequences. Are consumers too reliant on US card networks,
which recently withdrew their services from Russia, demonstrating that
even private payment systems can become drawn into international
conflicts? Are alternative systems needed to improve the economy’s
resilience to system outages, natural disasters or cyberattacks? Does it
matter if there is no longer a public alternative to private payment
services like card payments? And will consumers who value the privacy of
cash adopt riskier alternatives like Bitcoin or stablecoins, some of
which have been recently proven to be unsafe stores of value?
Nearly all central banks globally – including those in the EU, UK and US
– are examining retail central bank digital currencies (CBDCs) such as
the ‘digital euro’ as a potential answer to these concerns. Many are
ploughing ahead with pilots already.
A retail CBDC would allow
consumers access to electronic money backed by the central bank. Today,
only commercial banks generally have this privilege, in the form of
central bank reserves. Individuals can hold central bank money, but only
in physical form – as banknotes and coins. When individuals hold funds
electronically, those funds only represent a claim on the private bank
that manages the account, not the central bank.
However, everyday
consumers in Europe may find this revolution to be an academic one.
Europe’s banking sector is robust and deposits are guaranteed up to a
generous limit. Consumers, quite reasonably, consider bank savings to be
about as safe as cash. And CBDCs would probably be provided via
commercial banks, and could allow payments through a mobile app, a card,
or a similar device. So a CBDC could look similar to any bank account
today. State-backed savings options are already available for those who want them.
Whether
consumers and retailers would actually prefer to use a CBDC for
payments – rather than private payment services like today’s cards – is
therefore not obvious. Some central bankers
imply usage is unimportant, arguing that a CBDC merely needs to exist
as an ‘anchor’, giving consumers certainty that money can be withdrawn
from the private banking system. But cash still serves that purpose –
and if the problem is that fewer consumers and retailers use cash, then a
CBDC would only be a solution if it was more widely used instead. Other commentators
assume the bigger risk is overenthusiastic adoption, in particular that
CBDCs will be used for investment purposes and not just to make
payments. They worry that if consumers can quickly shift their bank
deposits into CBDCs, rather than needing to withdraw cash, banks would
become more vulnerable to runs. And if consumers have more of their
savings in CBDCs and less in bank deposits, then banks will need more
expensive wholesale funding to provide loans to customers. That would
drive up the cost of finance for households and businesses. To deal with
this problem, CBDCs would need limitations – such as caps on individual
holdings or unattractive interest rates – to limit the risks to private
banks. But that will reduce its attractiveness to users: existing
payment services do not generally have these limitations.
The primary objectives of a CBDC therefore cannot be achieved unless it is “available everywhere” and can win market share from today’s card payments. Yet CBDCs will struggle to compete.
First,
consider price: a CBDC should be financially attractive to both
consumers and retailers. Some retailers could be enticed to accept it: many
are concerned about the fees associated with accepting payment cards
like Visa, Mastercard and American Express, despite regulatory reforms
in 2015 which reduced these fees. A recent UK study
showed that smaller retailers pay, on average, nearly 2 per cent of a
total transaction’s value to accept cards. Cash is not getting more
attractive either: it slows down the speed of transactions; carries
risks of theft and loss; and as Chart 1 shows, retailers must pay more to deposit and handle cash
as its usage declines. A CBDC could do better: it could be cheap like
cash; and like electronic payments, it would be quick and safe to use....
more at CER
© CER
Key
Hover over the blue highlighted
text to view the acronym meaning
Hover
over these icons for more information
Comments:
No Comments for this Article