Follow Us

Follow us on Twitter  Follow us on LinkedIn
 

28 May 2021

Oliver Wyman: Central Bank Digital Currencies - Six policy mistakes to avoid


Central Bank Digital Currencies (CBDCs) are coming and it is important to do them right. There is strong momentum in key nations for central banks to create digital versions of their currencies for widespread use.

Bermuda has its “sand dollar”; China is well into its experimentation phase, as is Sweden; the European Central Bank is seriously analyzing the idea with President Christine Lagarde indicating a digital Euro could be in use by 2025; and virtually every major central bank is extensively analyzing the possibility of issuance.

Unfortunately, there is a danger that a number of central banks may make one or more of six serious policy mistakes, described in this paper. Our concern is based on extensive discussions with senior central bankers and other relevant officials, as well as experts outside of the official sector. In essence, these errors all have their roots in bureaucratic and political constraints, combined with the novelty of this instrument, making them more difficult to avoid.

Raising these concerns is not a statement of opposition to CBDCs. They are a powerful policy tool that can be used, in conjunction with other policy tools, to achieve a number of objectives. It is up to each central bank, and other relevant policymakers, to weigh the pros and cons and to choose the optimal design and implementation for any CBDC they may issue. We are simply urging the avoidance of some critical errors.

One note on nomenclature: this discussion focuses on “retail CBDCs,” meaning ones that are designed for wide use in the economy and to be held by individuals and businesses broadly, as opposed to “wholesale CBDCs,” primarily used between financial institutions. For convenience, we will use “CBDC” in this paper, rather than repeating “retail” each time.

The six deadly sins

  • Siloed decision-making. CBDCs do not exist in isolation; policy regarding CBDCs, stablecoins, other digital assets, and the Payments ecosystem must fit together coherently
  • Putting off the hard choices about policy objectives
  • Ignoring other policy tools to reach these objectives
  • Creating the "Swiss Army Knife" of digital currencies
  • Downplaying political constraints and forces
  • Muddled communications

Siloed decision-making

CBDCs do not exist in isolation and they are only one policy tool of many to achieve the various policy objectives for which they might be used. CBDCs will be one part of a complex Payments ecosystem which also overlaps with digital assets, such as Bitcoin, that are not primarily payments vehicles. Thus, policy choices need to be coherent across at least the following areas:

  • Modernization of Payments systems
  • CBDCs themselves
  • Stablecoins
  • Digital assets that are not tied to conventional currencies

Few, if any, countries have one authority responsible for all four of these categories. Even if they do, the different parts of that authority may not coordinate as well as they should. The US and the European Union (EU) may be particularly prone to silo problems in this area, as noted below.


US and EU considerations

The problem in the US is that authority over financial policy is fragmented. The Federal Reserve (Fed) would be responsible for a digital dollar. Regulation of stablecoins and digital assets is split between at least the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC), the Commodities Future Trading Commission (CFTC), the Federal Trade Commission (FTC), and various state authorities. The Office of the Comptroller of the Currency (OCC) and Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) have important regulatory authorities over other aspects of the digital assets ecosystem. Payments policy is set by a mix of the Fed and state authorities and even at the Fed there is some division between authority at the Federal Reserve Board and the twelve district banks. And, of course, the Administration has an important role, including the authority of the Treasury Secretary as Chair of the Financial Stability Oversight Council, which has a coordinating role on financial regulation and related issues. One can easily imagine a number of ways in which policy across all these bodies might not mesh well.

The EU has some analogous issues with split responsibilities across different types of authorities. For example, there is currently a difference of opinion between the ECB and the European Commission and other Brussels bodies about the ECB’s legal authority to proceed on its own in regard to CBDCs. Further, the EU has additional issues resulting from the complexities of the European institutions and their interactions with national authorities.


There are a number of practical reasons why it is important to consider the bigger picture, of which CBDC is just a part. First, the existing banking and wider financial systems are built around the current roles of the central bank and commercial banks, including the importance of deposits as a funding source for banks, much of which is tied to payments activities that could be affected by CBDC. Every central bank is aware that a CBDC could cause disruptions, potentially severe ones, to the existing banking system. All the major central banks have a stated goal of minimizing this disruption, to the extent consistent with their core reasons for creating a CBDC. The devil, however, will be in the details, as discussed below.

Second, some of the reasons put forward for CBDCs center on weaknesses in current payments system and regulation. Therefore, it would be important to look at the full payments ecosystem, and other proposed changes to it, when considering issuance of a CBDC or designing the details. We elaborate on this point further below.

A third set of reasons for CBDC issuance center on a preference by many policymakers for public sector digital currencies over private sector ones. The larger the role for a CBDC, the less the need for stablecoins that effectively mimic a CBDC. However, one could easily imagine a scenario in which a central bank chooses to create a very limited CBDC, yet financial regulators hem in potential stablecoins with a high degree of constraints, leaving a gap in the regulated system that is filled by neither the public nor private sector, which could easily encourage unregulated forms of digital currencies. Or the reverse could occur, where central banks attempt to create an attractive CBDC, but private sector stablecoins flourish in a lightly regulated environment that enables them to be more attractive than the CBDC. As one gets into the details, there are many choices which should be harmonized between the structure of a CBDC and the regulation and supervision of stablecoins and other digital assets.

Putting off the hard choices about policy objectives

A typical central bank which is seriously investigating the potential for a CBDC has issued a white paper in which they describe perhaps seven future scenarios in which they would want to have a CBDC. Implicitly, and sometimes explicitly, these central banks do not feel a CBDC is currently necessary, but rather that it might be in the future and the very long lead time needed makes it imperative to investigate now.

The future scenarios usually center on some or all of the following trends or issues:

  • Severe decline in the use of cash in an economy
  • The need for faster, more sustainable and more resilient payments processes
  • The need to increase financial inclusion
  • The potential for private sector digital currencies to crowd out central bank money
  • The need to improve cross-border payments processes
  • The need to decrease fraud and illicit activity
  • The desire to facilitate innovation and open competition in a more digitized economy

Moving from top-down to bottom-up approaches, a number of central banks are running, or have run, technical experiments to understand the capabilities and constraints of the underlying technologies.

This top-down and bottom-up approach has been very reasonable, but will soon hit its limits. In particular, it is very hard to have an honest debate about moving forward with a CBDC, or about its detailed design, when the objectives are so unclear. A CBDC is a very powerful tool, but you cannot know whether it is the best tool for the task, or specifically how to design it, without knowing its purpose. Most central banks are at the stage of arguing for the need to be ready to create a tool, without getting into whether that tool should be a hammer or a screwdriver, much less whether the tasks will require a Philips-head screwdriver or a standard one, a large screwdriver or a small one, etc.

Central banks need to move from discussing scenarios to choosing specific policy objectives. If, as is likely, they want to achieve a number of different objectives, then they also need to prioritize them, at least roughly. Setting objectives is critical to the next two steps: (1) determining how CBDCs compare with, and interact with, other policy tools and (2) making specific structural design decisions.

Implications for structural design

There are a host of high-level structural design choices that policymakers must decide. These are very briefly described below, as full explanations would require much more space.

Who should have access to CBDCs?

In particular, will this be a retail CBDC, analogous to cash, or a wholesale one, limited to use by financial institutions? For purposes of this paper, we are confining the discussion to retail CBDC.

Will CBDC holders have a direct relationship with the central bank or will intermediaries, such as banks and Fintechs, be used?

Central banks in advanced economies are generally leaning strongly towards an intermediary model, sometimes using “digital wallets.”

Will the system be account-based, token-based, or some combination?

Holders could be required to prove their identity in order to use CBDC in an account-based model or could have a digital token, the equivalent of paper money or coins, in which they only need to hold the token in order to use CBDC – a so-called “bearer instrument” model.

Which intermediaries will be allowed?

Most central banks explicitly wish to avoid disrupting the commercial banking system more than necessary. Does this mean only banks should be the intermediaries or will Fintechs and Big Tech firms be included?

What capabilities should be built in?

Digital currencies can be designed to allow or facilitate the use of “smart contracts” and “programmable money”. As part of this, a CBDC could be designed in such a way as to automate the execution of policy, for example, by delivering “helicopter payments” with automatic expiry dates as a form of monetary stimulus.

What limits will be in place for users and intermediaries?

Some central banks are exploring caps on the quantity of CBDCs that any specific individual can hold to limit financial disintermediation. How this is monitored and enforced may have implications to design.

How will data privacy/anonymity be handled?

There are a multitude of complex considerations in this area, revolving around which entities will have which data and how they are permitted to use it.

How will the system discourage money laundering and financial crimes?

This ties into the data privacy question. At one extreme, digital tokens could be as anonymous as cash, potentially making money laundering easier. At the other extreme, tokens or accounts could be tracked closely, reducing crime at the expense of privacy.

 

Optimal design choices will depend on which policy objectives are seen as the most crucial and as being consistent with the evolving role of the central bank. For example, an emphasis on financial inclusion might argue for a tighter relationship between the individual and the central bank, such as through an account at the central bank itself. In contrast, a focus on faster payments might put a premium on the use of intermediaries, which are already experienced at handling customer relationships and whose role would allow the central bank to avoid building a huge new infrastructure of accounts.

Similarly, if the goal is to mimic features of cash like its anonymity, the choice may be to ensure clear limits to data collection or guarantee anonymity through technology, for example, by adopting a token-based system that does not track the identity of the payer. On the other hand, if there is greater priority on combating illicit financial activities, such as money laundering and financing terrorism, then a system that collects more information on accumulation and usage is preferred.

Ignoring other policy tools to reach these objectives

There are alternative policy tools available to achieve virtually all of the objectives. For example, many central banks and private sector providers are in the process of dramatically increasing the speed of payments or have already done so. In terms of improving cross-border payments, the Financial Stability Board and the Committee on Payments and Market Infrastructures laid out 19 tools in their Stage 2 report on cross-border payments. CBDC is just one of these 19. Similarly, there are a host of potential tools to improve financial inclusion, many of them moving forward today.

This is not to argue against CBDCs, but to emphasize that once we know the policy objectives it will be critical to see what CBDCs are most useful for, either instead of other tools or, more likely, as a complement to them. There could be specific instances when a CBDC is the ideal tool. For example, the Bahamas adopted a CBDC blockchain structure for its sand dollar to help manage a specific set of constraints: limited connectivity and sporadic presence of financial institutions across a widely dispersed archipelago.

Creating the "Swiss Army Knife" of digital currencies

Unfortunately, there is a strong temptation to proceed forward with design of a CBDC, or at least publicly floating some specific design choices that may create strong momentum for those particular choices, prior to accepting the political pain of narrowing down and prioritizing the objectives. This creates a further temptation to “square the circle” by loading the technical requirements with a wide array of demands, so that when policymakers eventually settle on their goals, the CBDC design will support them.

The problem is that this is likely to result in a “Swiss Army knife” approach. The Swiss Army knife is a brilliant design, allowing the user to access many different tools in a compact space. However, it has only a very small share of the global tool market because it is virtually always better to use one or two or three tools that are optimized for the particular task. As with almost all major policy initiatives, the implementation will be much better if the objectives are clear from the beginning.

Some may be relying on the magic of innovative technology to rid them of the need to make these choices now. As good as our technologists are, it is much more likely that important design trade-offs will remain. Further, as discussed above, some policy choices are inherently at odds with others, such as certain trade-offs between anti-money laundering efforts and privacy requirements. (To be clear, privacy and AML considerations are not completely in conflict, but there are some aspects where one has to choose.)

Downplaying political constraints and forces

Choices about CBDC issuance and design will significantly affect the financial system and larger society. As a result, central banks will not be able to proceed in isolation or make decisions purely on their views about the technical merits of different approaches. Central bankers are aware of this, but there is a danger that they downplay the importance of politicians and other stakeholders, through a combination of a legitimate desire to protect their independence in monetary policy and a culture of trying to hold political considerations at arm’s length.

In general, CBDCs will need to be designed in close consultation with finance ministries and financial regulators, as well as the broader public, given their potentially large impacts on the financial system and critical importance of payments infrastructure to the economy. In this sense, the division of responsibilities and accountability for CBDC design is much more akin to the situation for financial regulation than for monetary policy. In most countries, central banks play a major role in regulating and supervising the financial sector and are more constrained and more closely watched by the political authorities for these activities than for monetary policy. That said, the consultation will need to be managed carefully to avoid the appearance or reality of undercutting the independence of central banks in monetary policy.

Moving on to specific decisions, there are two areas in particular where central bankers may believe they have more freedom than they will have in practice. First, many central banks are considering placing limitations on the amount of CBDC that can be held by any one individual or entity, in order to keep CBDC as primarily a payments vehicle and not a store of value that competes with bank deposits. However, if the new CBDC works well, it is difficult to imagine that central banks will be able to resist the high level of pressure that will arise to raise the limit to levels high enough that virtually any transaction can be performed with it. The ECB has floated the idea of limiting a digital euro to 3,000 euros per holder; one can easily see demands to raise that to 10,000 or 20,000 or higher, so that individuals and small businesses can buy automobiles or pay for an expensive trip. This pressure will be particularly hard to resist as the main reason for the limit is to avoid excessive disruption of the current banking system, which can easily be caricatured as the elites protecting the big banks – never a popular position.

Second, central banks would prefer to pay little or no interest on their CBDCs. This is partly to avoid disrupting the banking system too much and partly, one presumes, to preserve the financial benefits to central banks of being able to issue currency for free. If interest rates in the economy are very low, as they are currently in some countries, this may not be a major issue. However, any significant difference between what banks pay on deposits and what CBDCs accrue is likely to provoke anger that the “people’s bank” is treating citizens worse than the profit-seeking banks are.

Muddled communications

Good communications will be critical, given the importance of money and payments to the economy and therefore the wide range of stakeholders: the public; politicians; the media; financial institutions; tech firms; merchants; other types of businesses; etc. This will be challenging and easy to get wrong, particularly because there is a wide range of understanding about money across the stakeholders. We have had conversations with otherwise intelligent and well-informed individuals who literally thought that when a bank took a deposit, it placed those funds in a safe deposit box. More commonly, the great majority of the public makes no distinction between “money” they hold in a deposit account at a bank and “money” that represents a direct liability of a central bank. Further, we have already seen media coverage that equates CBDCs with Bitcoin, despite the potentially huge differences between the two types of instruments.

Good communications will be particularly important in driving adoption of a CBDC once it has been designed. This requirement goes beyond clarity to persuasion. Clear communications are critical, but a persuasive message also needs to resonate.

The need for good communications is another strong reason why policymakers need to be clear about their objectives and prioritizations. If policymakers are not clear, how can we expect the other stakeholders to understand clearly?

Communications choices can have important implications that may not be clear on first glance. For instance, most central banks are likely to go with an intermediated version of CBDC, whereby banks and some other authorized intermediaries will have the direct relationship with the holders of the CBDC. One reason for this choice is to take advantage of the intermediaries’ abilities to handle AML and other duties. However, if major money laundering problems occur, it may be difficult for central banks to shield themselves from blame to the extent they can today, if there has been a strong stress that this is a CENTRAL BANK digital currency.

As a second example, there is a risk of confusion around the level of privacy of transacting with CBDCs, as the level of privacy will depend not only on the choices made in its design, but the country’s broader privacy and data protection regime. While a CBDC may be designed to be private from central banks, data and metadata may be captured by intermediaries and combined with other data sources in ways that violate citizen’s perceptions of the CBDC’s level of privacy.

Additionally, the introduction of CBDCs may also change expectations from the public about monetary and fiscal policy. If a CBDC is messaged as a way for central banks to respond more effectively to economic challenges, then it may be more difficult to resist calls for central bankers to engage in novel monetary stimulus measures, such as helicopter money.

Conclusions

There is clear momentum for retail CBDCs and we believe they are likely to be built in many jurisdictions this decade. It is important that policymakers design and implement them well, which is why we have emphasized six areas where the risks of an error are particularly high.

 


Douglas J. Elliott is an Oliver Wyman partner focused on the intersection of Finance and public policy. He is the author of the book, Uncle Sam in Pinstripes: Evaluating US Federal Credit Programs. Prior to his current position, he was a scholar at the Brookings Institution and a Visiting Scholar at the IMF. Before that, he was the founder and principal researcher for the Center On Federal Financial Institutions. He began his career with two decades as an investment banker, primarily at JP Morgan.  


Larissa de Lima is a Fellow with the Oliver Wyman Forum, a think tank committed to bringing together business, public policy, and social enterprise leaders to create innovative solutions to the world’s toughest problems. She’s part of the Forum’s Future of Data Initiative, focused on enabling responsible data-driven innovation. Prior to this role, she worked at Oliver Wyman advising financial services clients on adapting to technological and regulatory change.


Oliver Wyman



© Oliver Wyman


< Next Previous >
Key
 Hover over the blue highlighted text to view the acronym meaning
Hover over these icons for more information



Add new comment