I will argue that in a digital world CBDCs are necessary to preserve the role of central bank money as a stabilising force at the heart of the payments system and to safeguard monetary sovereignty.
It is a great pleasure to take part in this panel on central bank digital currencies (CBDCs).
Throughout history, money and payments have been constantly evolving. And
this also holds true in the digital age. As we increasingly pay
digitally and shop online, we rely less on cash. Our wallets are
gradually moving from our pockets to smartphones and other electronic
devices.
These changes have profound implications for the nature of money
itself, raising the question of whether central banks should issue
digital currencies for retail use.
Today I will argue that in a digital world CBDCs are necessary to
preserve the role of central bank money as a stabilising force at the
heart of the payments system and to safeguard monetary sovereignty.
But CBDCs will need to be carefully designed. To be successful, they
will need to add value for users, support competition rather than crowd
out private innovation, and avoid risks to financial intermediation.
Why we need central bank digital money
Our monetary system is based on the complementarity of private money
with public money – which is available for retail payments in the form
of banknotes.
Confidence in private means of payment is determined by our ability
to convert private money into safe public money. This is because central
bank money is a risk-free form of money that is guaranteed by the
State: by its strength, its credibility, its authority.
Other types of money are liabilities of private issuers: their value
is based on the soundness of the issuer and is underpinned by the
promise of one-to-one convertibility with central bank money.
Our readiness to hold private money such as bank deposits reflects the
confidence that we can always go to a branch or a cash machine and
convert our deposits into cash. The fact that we can do this tells us
that our deposits are safe. It reassures us that we will be able to
convert them into risk-free central bank money in the future, too.
Bank runs and financial crises start when confidence in the convertibility of private money evaporates.
Without the anchor of sovereign money, people would constantly have to
monitor the soundness of private issuers in order to assess the value of
each form of private money. This would undermine confidence in the
singleness of money and impair the functioning of the payments system.
History provides examples for this. In times when various forms of
private money coexisted in the absence of sovereign money – such as the
free banking era of the 19th century – the notes issued by banks often
traded at variable prices and instability risks required dominant banks and clearinghouses to act as quasi-central banks.
The consensus among central banks on the coexistence between public and private money was summarised 20 years ago as follows: “The
composite of central and commercial bank money, convertible at par, is
essential to the safety and efficiency of the financial system and
should remain the basis of the singleness of the currency. In other
words, central banks would accept neither an outcome in which central
bank money crowds out private initiative, nor an outcome in which
central bank money is phased out by a market mechanism.”
In the digital age, however, banknotes could lose their role as a
reference value in payments, undermining the integrity of the monetary
system. Central banks must therefore consider how to ensure that their money can remain a payments anchor in a digital world.
Some have suggested that innovative private payment solutions such
as stablecoins could, if properly regulated, make CBDCs superfluous. However, confidence in stablecoins would also depend on the ability to convert them into central bank money,
unless stablecoin issuers were allowed to invest the reserve assets in
risk-free deposits at the central bank. But this would be tantamount to
outsourcing the provision of central bank money, which would endanger
monetary sovereignty.
Moreover, in the absence of public money, stablecoins could exacerbate
the “winner-takes-all” dynamics inherent in payment markets, with
adverse consequences for the functioning of the payments system. And stablecoins’ potentially large investments in safe assets could affect the availability of these assets.
This could in turn have an impact on market functioning and real
interest rates, with undesirable implications from a monetary policy
perspective.
Other threats to monetary sovereignty could emerge in the absence of a domestic digital currency.
If a foreign CB
DC were to be widely adopted, this could lead to digital currency substitution.
This risk would be higher for small countries with unstable currencies
and weak fundamentals, especially if the CB
DC were issued in a major
economy. But it could eventually also affect leading currencies.
ECB
© ECB - European Central Bank
Key
Hover over the blue highlighted
text to view the acronym meaning
Hover
over these icons for more information
Comments:
No Comments for this Article