Some countries have issued their own central bank digital currencies, and many European economists favour such a currency too. This column shows that when properly designed, central bank digital currencies can help stabilise the financial and monetary system.
Furthermore, a complementary currency backed by a central bank digital currency can not only compensate for the demise of commercial bank money, but it can also democratise money creation. The authors also show that complementary currencies can have higher multiplier effects on local expenditure, allow central banks to control circulation velocity, and help countries in currency crises.
China has banned
private cryptocurrencies (Olcott 2021) and launched its own central bank
digital currency (CBDC). We now have a race between countries to issue
their own CBDC.
In the UK, the House
of Lords committee has concluded there is no convincing case for the
creation of a CBDC (Mozée 2022) and that it could cause bank runs.
According to the Centre for Macroeconomics, however, 84% of the European
economists surveyed favour a CBDC (Crumpton and Ilzetki 2021), and so
do we. We are economists specialising in the management and study of
electronic community or ‘complementary’ currencies on a regional scale
in Spain, Switzerland, and Germany. Our experience shows that CBDCs,
properly designed, can help stabilise our financial and monetary system.
But first, what is
likely from the introduction of CBDCs? It could just mean that central
bank accounts would be available to everyone, not just to banks. Most
people would probably opt to move their money from their checking
account to a central bank deposit, since the latter is safer. This could
cause bank runs, which worries the House of Lords. But runs can be
avoided if there is a gradual transition to the amount of CBDC each
citizen is permitted. Establishing such limits is only possible if the
CBDC is not a private cryptocurrency but rather a central bank deposit.
Making central bank
deposits available to all citizens is a simple change that can
eventually transform the monetary system as we know it. Given that banks
create new money (deposits) out of thin air whenever they make loans,
any public preference for central bank deposits over commercial banks
could make this old money creation mechanism non-viable. Banks would
have to generate new credit products, transforming themselves into more
‘normal’ businesses in the process.
If most people hold
CBDCs instead of checking accounts, banks would no longer be ‘too big to
fail’. In the event of bankruptcy, the system of electronic payments
would continue, hosted by the central bank, eliminating the need for a
public bailout. This point is stressed by Miguel Angel Fernández
Ordóñez, the Bank of Spain’s former governor, in his book, Adiós a los bancos.
Because they are insured against their outsized risks, banks regularly
earn outsized profits. With a CBDC, the long-term trend of nonfinancial
corporations earning an ever-smaller share of corporate profits would be
curbed, resulting in a more balanced distribution of income, as seen in
the following US series (Figure 1).
Figure 1 Nonfinancial corporate business: Profits after tax
Source: https://fred.stlouisfed.org/graph/?g=Nprc
The implementation
of CBDC and less money creation by banks would mean greater systemic
stability for another reason: bank money is highly ‘pro-cyclical’.
Central banks could issue CBDCs counter-cyclically, moderating economic
cycles rather than magnifying them. As Yale economist Irving Fisher
wrote in 1935, ending private banks’ ability to create money would both
nationalise money and fully privatise banking. More recently, former
Bank of England Governor Mervyn King (2010) argued that “[o]f all the
many ways of organising banking, the worst is the one we have today”.
Nonetheless, many
fear that a CBDC will give the government a window on every transaction,
ending the anonymity of cash. But with almost three-quarters of the
value of US consumer purchases now electronic (Federal Reserve Bank of
San Francisco 2019), this window is already open to a valid search
warrant. Legitimate purchases with a CBDC can be similarly shielded. On
the other hand, there is a real security gain in combating laundered
money. Current efforts to track the assets of Russian oligarchs have
brought this to the fore. Novokmet (2018) and his colleagues conclude
that Russian secretion of private wealth abroad is unparalleled in
modern history and now totals as much as 100% of their country’s annual
GDP.
There is much more
hidden wealth to be taxed. The 2020 UN High-Level Panel on International
Financial Accountability, Transparency and Integrity (FACTI) estimates
show a 2019 tax loss of about $600 billion. Using World Bank figures on
global tax/GDP ratios and global GDP,1 one can estimate this loss at 4.61% of global tax revenues. This global tax to GDP ratio is an average,
so the progressivity of statutory tax rates, both within and between
countries, means this estimate of tax loss is highly conservative. ...
more at VOX
© VoxEU.org
Key
Hover over the blue highlighted
text to view the acronym meaning
Hover
over these icons for more information
Comments:
No Comments for this Article