Later this year we expect the European Commission to issue the legislative proposals to implement the final package of the reforms agreed by the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (BCBS).
Rather predictably, my remarks tonight will focus on banking issues.
More specifically, I would like to talk about international banking
regulation. Later this year we expect the European Commission to issue
the legislative proposals to implement the final package of the reforms
agreed by the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (BCBS). This last
step completes the policy response to the great financial crisis. The
Governors and Heads of Supervision (GHOS) in turn have committed to
refrain from launching major adjustments to the international standards
for the foreseeable future.
But
the last lap of this long process is still facing fierce opposition
from some in the banking industry who argue that the impact of the
reforms might adversely affect banks’ capacity to support the recovery
from the coronavirus (COVID-19) pandemic shock. I am firmly convinced
that a full and timely implementation of this last set of international
standards is in the interest of all stakeholders. It requires only
limited adjustments in the short term but will deliver the necessary
structural improvements to our regulatory framework as well as sizeable
and long-lasting benefits for our economies. Most importantly, I believe
that the effectiveness of international standards, which is of great
value to supervisory authorities and international banks alike,
crucially relies on the commitment of all signatories to faithfully
implement them in their domestic jurisdictions.
Before I go into
the detail of the final stretch of this journey – the implementation of
the final Basel III package – I would like to briefly look back on how
the journey began and how banks’ internal models, which the package
addresses, came to the fore of international discussions.
The BCBS
was established in the mid-1970s after the collapse of the German bank
Herstatt. Its creation reflected the awareness that, after three decades
of financial stability (although some would perhaps say three decades
of financial repression), the collapse of the Bretton Woods system of
fixed exchange rates and the ensuing free-floating exchange rate system
had given new momentum to the international banking business, and
banking regulation and supervision needed to catch up.
As well documented by Charles Goodhart in his excellent book on the early years of the Basel Committee,
the newly constituted Committee was initially more concerned about
supervisory cooperation than standard setting. The Basel Committee’s
first document of note was in fact the Basel Concordat. In the wake of
the collapse of Herstatt, the Concordat sought to set out the respective
responsibilities of what we refer to in supervisory jargon as the
“home” and the “host” authorities of international banking groups, as
well as their duties of cooperation. The Concordat was revised in the
aftermath of other international banking crises, like that of Banco
Ambrosiano, and remained for many years the main point of reference for
the activities of the Committee, and its main focus was international
supervisory cooperation.
The standard-setting drive came later, as
it became clear that supervisory cooperation, which sought to avoid
disruptive crises of international banking groups, and standard setting,
which aimed to foster an international level playing field, were
closely connected. Competing regulatory standards from different
jurisdictions endangered the very possibility of global financial
stability and, in the end, would threaten both the level playing field
across regional markets (including the United States and Europe) and the
feasibility of international supervisory cooperation.
That is
why, to effectively fulfil their national mandates, the national
competent authorities and the central banks of the most relevant banking
jurisdictions in the world not only had to cooperate ex post – in the
run-up or, worse, in the aftermath of the crisis of a specific bank –
but they also had to cooperate ex ante, so to speak, to align the
regulatory requirements of internationally active banks at the technical
level. The firm commitment by all participants to transpose what had
been agreed in Basel into legally binding legal acts in each national
jurisdiction – or supranational in Europe’s case – coupled with the peer
review of the existing legislative frameworks, completed the
institutional set-up of this global standard-setting body and laid the
foundations of its credibility and reputation vis-à-vis banks and other
market participants at the global level.
Now, it is important to
underscore that Basel regulatory cycles are very long policymaking
processes that take many years to complete. The highly technical nature
of the subject matter requires detailed discussions at the negotiating
table, consultations with the industry, impact assessment exercises and
appropriate transitional periods to be defined before the new rules can
actually become fully applicable. This last point is crucial to avoid
disrupting the macroeconomic cycle with sudden changes in the regulatory
requirements which modify incentives, alter the functioning of banks’
business models and, ultimately, affect the allocation of financial
resources to the real economy.
Let’s take the first Basel
Capital Accord as our starting point. Negotiations on a global
regulatory capital standard for banks had already started in the early
1980s in the aftermath of the Latin American debt crisis, but the
Committee only reached an agreement in 1988, with an implementation date
being set for the end of 1992. This was achieved in the European Union
(or European Community, as it was at the time) in 1989 through a suite
of Directives, including the Solvency Ratio Directive and the Second
Banking Coordination Directive, which were then transposed into the
legal frameworks of all Member States.
Compared with the later accords, Basel I was notable for its simplicity
but also its very limited scope for risk sensitivity. It established a
simple minimum capital requirement of 8% of own funds of variable
quality (common equity could, in the end, be as low as 2% of
risk-weighted assets) and a few coarse risk weights for specified asset
classes divided into 0%, 20%, 50% and 100% risk buckets. One of the key
trade-offs in prudential regulation – between the simplicity of the
rules and their risk sensitivity – would soon take centre stage.
Two
developments made supervisory authorities realise that these
broad-brush requirements were fast becoming obsolete. First, exactly in
the same years of the definition of the Accord banks’ internal risk
management techniques started to become more sophisticated,
so that the risk sensitivity of the regulatory framework was falling
out of touch with best market practices for the internal allocation of
economic capital. Second, research conducted by the Federal Reserve
System showed that banks had managed to develop a number of practices,
such as expanding off-balance sheet activities, like securitisation, or
adjusting effective exposures to risk within the broad buckets defined
by the first Accord, to increase their level of risk-taking without
being captured by regulatory requirements.
The need to bring
regulation closer to the real risks involved in certain activities and
prevent regulatory arbitrage opened the door to the regulatory
recognition of banks’ internal models. If it was possible to measure
risk in a more granular fashion for risk management purposes, then the
same method should be used to quantify regulatory capital, as it would
make the regulatory framework more efficient and more
incentive-compatible.
In this context, in 1996 a market risk
amendment to the Basel I Accord was agreed. For the first time, banks
could use internal risk models to calculate regulatory requirements for
market risk (but not credit risk). With the second Basel Capital Accord
(known as Basel II), which was agreed in 2004 to become applicable in
2007, the internal model approach was extended to the calculation of
capital requirements for credit risk, counterparty credit risk and
operational risk.
The use of internal models was embedded in prudential requirements to
calculate risk-weighted exposure amounts, the denominator of the capital
requirement ratio.
It is sometimes erroneously argued that this
move towards the use of internal models in the calculation of capital
requirements was at the origin of the great financial crisis. Some
critics saw the reform as epitomising a broader policy shift towards
deregulation of financial markets. For these critics, relying on banks’
own internally developed methodologies to calculate their regulatory
requirements was like letting the fox guard the chicken coop.
In
actual fact, some of the jurisdictions at the epicentre of the great
financial crisis, such as the United States, had not yet allowed banks
to use internal models. The Basel Committee’s “use test”, which required
banks to use the same models for internal risk management purposes as
for the calculation of regulatory requirements, was intended to foster
reliance on best market practices. And the ease with which sophisticated
international banks managed to circumvent the simpler regulatory
requirements of Basel I had, in the end, left the international
supervisory community with no credible alternative.
Yet, it would
be equally misleading to overlook the weaknesses in banks’ internal
models and their use for regulatory purposes that were highlighted
during the crisis. The regulatory framework for market risk had to be
amended in 2009 because of shortcomings in the ability of value at risk
(VaR) models to capture default risk and migration risk, with stressed
VaR requirements introduced as a result.
What’s more, the
increase in the risk sensitivity of prudential requirements caused by
the Basel II standards generally led to an unintended reduction of risk
density, i.e. the average risk weight for the largest and
internationally active banks, and to unwarranted variability in
risk-weighted assets, meaning similar portfolios were carrying vastly
different capital charges without apparent differences in the underlying
risk.
As the risk density decreased, banks were able to carry
out more business based on the same absolute amount of own funds, thus
expanding their balance sheets. They increased their leverage while
still complying with the risk-weighted capital requirements and, in some
cases, even increased their regulatory ratios.
This is well
documented in a 2014 report by the European Systemic Risk Board’s
Advisory Scientific Committee. The report shows that in the run-up to
the great financial crisis, the median risk-weighted capital ratio – so
Tier 1 capital to risk weighted assets – remained almost stable at
around 8%, whereas the leverage ratio fell by almost half. By 2008 the
median leverage ratio of the 20 largest European banks had dropped to
just over 3% (assets were 32 times capital) from a previous average of
6% (17 times), while median risk-weighted regulatory capital ratios
remained essentially unchanged.
An even more striking finding
from the report is the negative correlation between the risk-weighted
Tier 1 capital ratio and the equity-to-assets ratio, another measure of
leverage. In short, banks that were more capitalised on a risk-weighted
basis also had a lower leverage ratio, something that in itself called
for a careful investigation into the role of the risk-weighted assets
framework, and internal models, in banking regulation.
Other analyses
show that shortly before the great financial crisis, the average
risk-weighted solvency ratio of the large international banks that
entered resolution or needed government support was well above the
minimum requirements and not statistically different from the average
solvency ratio of the banks that did not experience a crisis. The Tier 1
capital ratios appeared uninformative about banks’ true default
probabilities and, therefore, the actual risks on their balance sheets.
We
all know the intrinsic limitations of risk measurement models and the
implications of their use for regulatory purposes. Of course, it is as
much a supervisory problem as it is a regulatory one. As a supervisor I
have always been deeply interested in the risk sensitivity of capital
requirements. Intellectually, it seems clear that riskier assets should
attract higher capital charges than less risky ones. But the real issue,
which is almost a philosophical question, is whether financial risk can
be accurately measured. As you probably know, there are splendid pages
by Keynes, among others, on the irreducible uncertainty of economic
outcomes and the impossibility of measuring real risk through
probabilistic calculations.
To make this fundamental problem more tractable, supervisory
authorities need to be in a position to robustly challenge banks’
modelling choices and their conservatism....
More at EBA
© ECB - European Central Bank
Key
Hover over the blue highlighted
text to view the acronym meaning
Hover
over these icons for more information
Comments:
No Comments for this Article