ECB announcement that both Bulgaria and Croatia were required entry to ‘close cooperation’ with their respective central banks ... after fulfilling the necessary supervisory and legislative steps prior to the inclusion of their respective currencies in the Exchange Rate Mechanism II (ERM II).
The move towards greater monetary
integration requires appropriate banking supervision to ensure the
stability of the ensuing cross-border credit flows between the
respective groups of countries. Together, these two steps pave the way
for Bulgaria’s and Croatia’s future participation in the euro area. It
is evident from the research undertaken in this paper that there are
clear benefits of close cooperation for these Member States whose
domestic currencies were already linked to the euro, in view of the
dominant position euro area banks have in their respective domestic
markets. Those banks channel the likely strong expansion of credit that
goes hand in hand with the participation in the ERM II as shown in the
latest round of participation (Estonia, Lithuania, Slovenia, Latvia and
Slovakia). It is more difficult for a national authority to exercise
discretion in implementing ECB decisions once it is committed to the
path leading to full European Monetary Union (EMU) membership. The
uncertainty about the functioning and durability of the
close-cooperation arrangement is largely removed.
The establishment of the
Monetary Union and the Banking Union in Europe greatly advanced
integration among Member States, but also raised questions about how to
achieve effective coordination between euro area institutions and
counterparts in non-member European countries, and how those
non-members might transition towards inclusion in those unions if they
chose to follow that path. This Policy Brief addresses certain aspects,
focusing on the cases of Bulgaria and Croatia, countries which recently
initiated close cooperation with the Banking Union and committed
themselves to abide by the ERM II. More details can be found in our
recent paper (Nieto and Singh, 2021).
It had always been envisaged that
non-euro area countries could join the Monetary Union after a successful
“probationary period” under the ERM II. However, the roadmap for
Monetary Union did not shape the way non-euro area countries would join
the Banking Union and enter in close cooperation in banking supervision
and crisis management.
In the cases of Bulgaria and Croatia,
the ECB Governing Council adopted a decision to establish close
cooperation with the other relevant central banks following the
fulfilment of the necessary supervisory and legislative prerequisites.2 In parallel, the inclusion of their respective currencies in the ERM II was announced.3
Participation in the ERM II is a precondition for as well as fulfilment
of the nominal convergence criteria to join the euro, and as such it is
binding and of a temporary nature. It should be noted that the
currencies of Bulgaria and Croatia were already closely tied to the euro
at the time of applying to the ERM II. Bulgaria had a currency board
(first with the deutschmark, and subsequently with the euro after 1999)
after a devastating debt and banking crisis in 1997. Croatia had a peg
first with the deutschmark, and from 1999 to the euro, with a narrow
band. All the countries that joined the ERM have become members of the
EMU with the sole exception of Denmark, which opted out of the
obligation to become a member for national political reasons.
Together, these two steps pave the way for Bulgaria’s and Croatia’s future participation in the euro area.
This is the first
time a Member State’s national currency would join ERM II since the
start of the EU banking union. Upon the introduction of the euro a
Member State now also joins the banking union, which is irreversible and
involves direct powers of the Single Supervisory Mechanism (SSM) and
the Single Resolution Mechanism (SRM) over its banking system.
Therefore, participating in ERM II with a view to later adopting the
euro also involves – for Bulgaria’s [and Croatia’s] as well as for any
other Member State’s national currency that will in the future join ERM
II – preparing for joining the banking union.4
After the launch of the SSM, as
an integral part of the institutional architecture of the euro, it was
rational that EU policymakers would expect EU Member States when joining
the ERM II to also require close cooperation with ECB. The
requirement for close cooperation when applying to the ERM II deals with
the ‘efficiency’ gaps in the pre-existing arrangements that neglect the
possibility of negative bank sovereign ‘loops’ (Nieto and Schinasi
(2007), Podstawski and Velinov (2018) and Dumitrescu-Pasecinic (2019)).
Against this background, as is the case for the ERM II, the
‘participation’ mechanism should be understood as a binding requirement
of a temporary nature until the applying country joins the EMU.
The SSM Framework (the SSM Regulation
(2013), the SSM Cooperation Framework Regulation (2014) and the 2014 ECB
Close Cooperation Decision) permits non-euro-area Member States to
participate in the SSM through a close-cooperation arrangement.5
In the cases of Bulgaria and Croatia,
the binding and temporary nature of the close-cooperation mechanism
highlights a particular case of the bespoke general governance
arrangements of the SSM Framework, in which the possibility of ‘opting
out’ fades with the incentives for joining the euro. The Figure below
presents the options open to non-euro EU countries in terms of
participation in the ERM II and/or the close-cooperation arrangement.
Only simultaneous participation with a view to joining the euro is
incentive compatible, as explained in this Policy Brief.
Figure: Options open to non-euro EU countries in terms of participation in the ERM II and/or the close-cooperation arrangement
Source: Authors’ analysis.
The SSM framework explains
how the Member States entering “close cooperation” within the SSM will
have a relationship with the ECB in the SSM which is ‘comparable’ but
not ‘equivalent’ to Member States of the euro area (Singh,
2020). The SSM framework confers on the ECB the right to instruct the
national authorities rather than directly supervise their significant
banks. Domestic legislation in the Member States, entering into “close
cooperation”, is required to mandate the national authorities to abide
by the ECB requests and guidelines. The right to suspend and terminate
the “close cooperation” arrangement remains in the SSM framework.
However, the commitment to join the Monetary Union minimises the
‘authority dilemma’ for the ECB since suspension and termination will
become a non-issue. Hence, the incentive for simultaneous application to
join the ERM II and to enter “close cooperation” is apparent, as the
political commitment for joining the Monetary Union and Banking Union
converge.
Close cooperation involves marked
changes in the allocation of related powers. In the case of a subsidiary
of Banking Union banks in a country outside “close cooperation,” the
ECB as the apex of the SSM can effectively impose conditions on the
subsidiary via the parent without formal involvement of the host
supervisor. When a close cooperation arrangement is in place, ECB
decisions addressed to supervised entities are replaced by instructions
to the respective national supervisor (termed the National Competent
Authority – NCA) and on occasion the macroprudential authority (termed
the National Designated Authority – NDA). The higher the proportion of
foreign euro area banks to domestic banks, the greater the need for
cooperation and coordination in order to minimise information
asymmetries and limit the risks of contagion from cross-border banking....
more at SUERF
© SUERF
Key
Hover over the blue highlighted
text to view the acronym meaning
Hover
over these icons for more information
Comments:
No Comments for this Article