On 10 November 2021, the European Fiscal Board (EFB)
published its new annual report (EFB 2021). The report provides an
assessment of the immediate fiscal policy response to the Covid-19
crisis and further updates the EFB’s reform proposal for the EU fiscal
framework to account for post-pandemic realities. The deep contraction
of over 6% – unprecedented in its severity since WWII – invalidated
earlier policy plans, which in many cases contained unambitious fiscal
targets, in particular for high-debt countries.
The Covid-19 impact on public finances in the EU
An explicit provision was introduced in the Stability and Growth Pact
(SGP) in 2011 to cater for Covid-like symmetric calamities, the ‘severe
economic downturn clause’ (in the public debate commonly known as the
‘general escape clause’). Its swift, and very first, activation, in
conjunction with the equally swift reaction of the ECB via the pandemic
emercency purchase programme (PEPP), provided the necessary room for
policy manoeuvre. Starting from March 2020, Member States have virtually
all enacted massive crisis-relief packages, so the budgetary impact was
more pronounced than after past major economic shocks, with the
deficits exceeding 9% of GDP in several Member States (see Figure 1).
This robust fiscal response coupled with the sharp drop in economic
activity led to an equally unprecedented increase in government
debt-to-GDP ratios by over 13 percentage points on average. Member
States with the highest debt before the crisis recorded the biggest
jumps in debt ratios, also linked to the fact that they happened to be
particularly hard hit by the pandemic.
Figure 1 Government balances in 2020 by country
Note: Estimates of the structural budget balance are
surrounded by uncertainty as they involve forecasts of real GDP. They
are likely to be revised when new data become available.
Source: European Commission’s spring 2021 economic forecast.
Overall, the swift and forceful reaction of both fiscal and monetary
authorities was warranted. It stands in sharp contrast to what happened
in the wake of the global financial and economic crisis and was, without
doubt, instrumental in softening the economic and social fallout of the
pandemic, at least for the short term. At the same time, the policy
response underscored at least two important and interlinked issues in
the EU fiscal surveillance framework: the notorious failure or
difficulty on the part of some Member States to build fiscal buffers in
good economic times, followed by the tendency to find new often forms of
flexibility in the implementation of the EU fiscal rules or through new
elements of risk sharing when times turn bad.
As was explained in previous EFB reports (e.g. Thygesen et al. 2020),
not all Member States had taken advantage of the protracted recovery
from the global economic and financial crisis to improve public
finances. A significant number of euro area Member States entered the
pandemic with a debt-to-GDP ratio well above pre-2007 levels and had
more limited or no budgetary leeway for responding to another major
economic shock. In light of the truly exogenous nature of the pandemic,
common EU initiatives created room for manoeuvre for this latter group
of countries as well. In particular, following difficult negotiations in
the Council the EU started the Next Generation EU (NGEU) initiative,
which involves substantial cross-country transfers. In addition, the
ECB’s PEPP programme very much helped mitigate early signs of stress on
certain euro area sovereigns and stabilise yields at low levels.
Nevertheless, as Figure 2 demonstrates, countries with less fiscal
headroom mobilised a comparatively smaller increase in government
expenditure in 2020; it remains true when one takes into account the
impact of the various liquidity support schemes, such as the
government-guaranteed lending programmes.
Figure 2 Net expenditure growth in 2020 (country groups by fiscal positions)
Notes: (1) The medium-term rate of potential GDP
growth is in nominal terms. It is calculated as the 10-year average of
real potential output growth rates plus the GDP deflator, taken as an
average over the same 10-year period. (2) Fiscal space reflects the
difference between the estimated structural budget balance and the
medium-term objective (MTO). The fiscal space for Greece is set to zero
due to fiscal commitments taken at the end of the economic programme.
(3) Net expenditure growth refers to the growth rate of government
expenditure in 2020 excluding some items (interest expenditure,
expenditure on EU programmes fully matched by EU funds revenue, and the
cyclical part of unemployment benefit expenditure) and is net of
discretionary revenue measures and one-offs. Investment expenditures are
averaged over four years. (4) Low debt countries = EE, LU, BG, CZ, SE,
DK, RO, LT, LV, MT, PL; High debt countries = NL, IE, SK, FI, DE, HU,
SI, AT, HR; Very high debt countries = CY, FR, BE, ES, PT, IT, EL.
Source: European Commission’s spring 2021 economic forecasts, EFB calculations.
To accommodate the fiscal response within the EU fiscal rules, the
Commission and the Council started early on to discuss various
flexibility options. They quickly agreed to resort to the severe
economic downturn clause. Although extra flexiblity was needed, the way
decisions were taken highlights issues in the implemenation of a
rules-based system. In particular, although designed to grant some
flexibility on a country-by-country basis around the requiremens of the
SGP, the severe economic downturn clause was communicated and applied
like a general waiver without real differentiation across countries.
Second, the timing or conditions for its deactivation were not addressed
until spring 2021, which in turn had been singled out by a number of
independent fiscal institutions as complicating factors to provide
guidance to national bugdetary authorities. Furthermore, official
Commission documents rightly insisted that the activation of the clause
did not mean the suspension of the SGP. However, the Commission and the
Council decided, citing the high degree of uncertainty surrounding the
economic outlook, not to launch any procedural follow-up when they
assessed clear cases of non-compliance, notably excessive deficits. This
approach was based on political considerations rather than established
practice or precedents. Excessive deficit procedures (EDPs) were
customarily opened for straightforward breaches of the deficit
criterion. At the current juncture, EDPs are clearly not to be used as
an instrument of frontloaded and abrupt fiscal adjustment, but could
still offer policy guidance and credibility for the medium term. The
extensive interpretation of the severe economic downturn clause, which
as described above gave rise to diverging interpretations as to the
procedural follow-up and the modalities of deactivation, is a
particularly visible symptom of the underlying challenge in the current
arrangements of EU fiscal surveillance: within the limits imposed by the
Treaty, discretion (when backed by the necessary majority in the
Council) trumps rules. A more organic review of the current set of
flexibilty clauses, taking into account the lessons learnt, is needed.
The case for a swift and comprehensive reform
The pandemic understandably froze the economic governance review
process initiated in early 2020; its recent relaunch by the Commission
was timely and more than welcome. Regardless of divergent perceptions
among Member States as to how to return to a rules-based fiscal
framework, the EFB believes in the significance of wide-ranging changes.
Our reform proposal organised around three central elements: i) a
medium-term debt anchor; ii) an expenditure rule as the main policy
instrument; and iii) a single escape clause applied on the basis of
independent analysis. It was basically laid out in detail before the
outburst of the pandemic (Beetsma et al. 2018, EFB 2019), and it gained
more relevance post-Covid. In fact, there is an emerging generation of
reform blueprints that are similar to the EFB’s.
The EFB is a strong advocate of maintaining reference values, as
clear and recognisable numerical goalposts play an important role in any
solid fiscal framework. They provide tangible focal points for public
debates and a basis for decision-makers’ accountability in the fiscal
domain. Concretely, the 3% of GDP deficit threshold remains a useful
backstop against unsustainable debt dynamics. The headline deficit is
observable, easy to interpret, and uniformly applicable to all EU
countries. It should remain the main triggering point for assessing the
opportunity to initiate corrective actions in a revised framework.
A revised EU fiscal framework should preferably be complemented by
additional policy levers enhancing its resilience and robustness. Beyond
the update of EU fiscal rules, there are other long-overdue governance
reforms in the EU, most notably the creation of a central fiscal
capacity and schemes to promote public investments, such as augmenting
the EU budget by dedicated national envelopes for providing EU common
goods. The availability of a joint fiscal capacity is all the more
important when monetary policy is constrained by the effective lower
bound and some Member States struggle with keeping public finances on a
sustainable path. Conditioning the access to the common instrument to
compliance with the fiscal framework may further encourage fiscal
responsibility across the EU. The recently established NGEU facility
consists partly of budgetary transfers, with strings attached as to how
they can be spent and to what reforms should be pursued, also with a
view to reverse the trend of declining government investment and to
improve the quality of public finances. The jury is still out whether
this initiative remains a one-off or it will lead to permanent
institutional changes.
In a scenario of no major changes to the SGP, EU institutions should
spell out transparently how the necessary flexibility and constrained
discretion vis-à-vis the ‘Maastricht numbers’ will be applied in the
coming period. Most importantly, the boundaries of flexibility should be
clarified. In this vein, routine channelling of the outcome of
bilateral negotiations between the Commission and national governments
through the Council should be abandoned.
Ideally, independent fiscal institutions should play a greater role
in the EU surveillance process, in particular outside the corrective
arm. While greater reliance on country-specific guidance by national
IFIs can have its clear benefits, the EFB sees limits to the reform
avenue of significant decentralisation. In a broad sense, national
fiscal institutions remain too heterogeneous in the EU to consistently
shape the conduct of fiscal policy. This insight is corroborated by our
annual report’s analysis of the early experiences with the national
correction mechanisms. Absent a conscious effort to harmonise the role
and functions of these entities, the Commission’s and the Council’s role
in monitoring performance and formulating recommendations will remain
essential.
Reforming the framework in time would serve the interests of both
groups of Member States: those keen to avoid a further erosion of the
rules-based system, and those willing to exploit flexibility in a
productive manner. By contrast, less predictable fiscal policy only
makes sudden risk repricing by financial markets more likely. Given the
two decades history of discretionary and hard-to-predict tweaks in the
implementation of the existing SGP rule book, reforming genuinely the
fiscal framework seems to be a far better approach.
References
Beetsma, R, N Thygesen, A Cugnasca, E Orseau, P Eliofotou and S Santacroce (2018), “Reforming the EU fiscal framework: A proposal by the European Fiscal Board”, VoxEU.org, 26 October.
Bénassy-Quéré, A, M Brunnermeier, H Enderlein, E Farhi, M Fratzscher,
C Fuest, P-O Gourinchas, P Martin, J Pisani-Ferry, H Rey, I Schnabel, N
Veron, B Weder di Mauro and J Zettelmeyer (2018), “Reconciling risk sharing with market discipline: A constructive approach to euro area reform”, CEPR Policy Insight No 91.
Darvas, Zs, P Martin, and X Ragot (2018), “European fiscal rules require a major overhaul”, Bruegel Policy Contribution No. 18.
EFB – European Fiscal Board (2019), “Assessment of EU fiscal rules with a focus on the six and two-pack legislation”.
EFB (2021), Annual Report 2021.
Martin, P, J Pisani-Ferry and X Ragot (2021), “Reforming the European Fiscal Framework”, Les notes du conseil d’analyse économique No 63., Conseil d'Analyse Économique
Thygesen, N, R Beetsma, M Bordignon, X Debrun, M Szczurek, M Larch, M Busse, M Gabrijelcic, E Orseau and S Santacroce (2020), “Reforming the EU fiscal framework: Now is the time” , VoxEU.org, 26 October.