The freezing of Russian foreign exchange reserves will have long-term and systemic consequences. This column argues that the dominant role of the dollar as a reserve currency will be unaffected. No other country can provide.. a large, liquid government bond market and a fully open capital account.
Sanctions may have significant long-term effects on the demand for reserves. Countries may reduce their dependence on reserves by limiting their exposure to financial shocks and partially restricting capital movements. The international monetary system may evolve towards to a new architecture, where cross-border financial integration is reduced.
Following
the invasion of Ukraine, the sanctions taken against Russia have been
unprecedented in scale and, above all, in scope. For the first time in
recent history, the foreign exchange reserves held by a major central
bank have been frozen. Reactions by Russian authorities show that this
was totally unexpected on their part (Berner et al. 2022). This column
presents some preliminary thoughts on the potential long-term and
systemic consequences in a context of geopolitical rivalry and
increasing ‘deglobalisation’, at least in respect to financial
transactions.
Sanctions and the dollar
A first question to
consider is whether the status of the dollar as the dominant
international currency could be put in doubt or risk. Our answer is
negative for three reasons.
- The freeze is
taking place in a situation that may be perceived as truly exceptional:
an armed conflict triggered by the invasion carried out by a major
country. No one would expect standard financial relations and
arrangements to hold in those circumstances. In comparable situations,
such as Japan’s war in Asia from 1937, cross-border payments were
eventually blocked. Gold owned by countries occupied or in war was not
handed over to the aggressor by the central banks that held it. Thus,
France and Britain refused to hand over the reserves of the Baltic
countries annexed by the Soviet Union in 1940. These are extreme and
rare circumstances.
- All actions taken
by the US authorities over the last decades demonstrate their commitment
to promote and preserve the dollar as a safe asset. Numerous facilities
have been deployed by the Federal Reserve to ensure the liquidity of
the Treasury market – some of them specially designed for official
foreign holders. The implicit government guarantee benefitting Fanny Mae
and Freddie Mac (which serve as a major instrument of foreign exchange
reserves) has been reaffirmed when necessary. With the possible
exception of the Trump administration, successive US Treasury
secretaries have been adamant that “a strong dollar is in the interest
of the United States”.
- Finally, attractive
alternatives to the US dollar do not exist and hence no realistic
diversification instrument is available. The power of the US to impose
sanctions derives directly from the central role of the dollar. For any
international corporation or financial institution, life without the
dollar is currently impossible. Therefore, any of their operation falls
potentially under US jurisdiction. All will remain under the reach of
sanctions so long as the dollar remains essential. Avoiding and
resisting sanctions means finding alternatives to the dollar. We are
therefore drawn back to an old, and still very acute question: are there
such alternatives?
International money, old and new
Money is about scale
and externalities. They come in two forms: network externalities – the
more people accept a currency the better it is as a medium of exchange;
and liquidity externalities – a true store of value remains tradable and
valuable in times of need (Brunnermeier et al. 2022). In the current
world economy, a crucial question concerns the causality between those
two functions.
The dominant
currency paradigm (Gopinath and Stein 2021) mainly attributes the
essentiality of the dollar to its role in global payments and finance –
emphasising the medium of exchange role and its function as a vehicle
currency for international financial flows. In the same vein,
Eichengreen (2010), based on his analysis of history of the interwar
period, sees a logical sequencing in the emergence of a global currency:
(1) invoicing and settling trade, (2) use in private financial
transactions (vehicle currency), (3) use by central banks as reserves.
If that sequence is
still valid, there are real prospects of alternative reserve currencies
emerging. China is the world’s major trading power. It has leverage to
push for the use of its currency as a medium of exchange and unit of
account. It could exploit its advance in the development of digital
currencies. A possible scenario would see both Alipay and Tencent expand
their international operations, progressively shifting their
denomination from local currencies to the renminbi. China is the most
advanced in developing a central bank digital currency. The introduction
of the e-yuan, already past its pilot phase, is often interpreted as an
offensive move to promote the RMB internationalisation.
Another, somehow
opposite, approach attributes the dollar dominance to its unique role as
a store of value, being the ultimate safe asset. There is nowhere else
to park several hundred billion with almost total security and
liquidity. That function is central in a financially globalised world
where both private and public entities must protect their liquidity.
From that role as a store of value, other functions derive, reversing
the causality that may have prevailed in other periods. Because it is a
reserve asset, it is convenient to also use the dollar for invoicing and
payments. It serves as a global unit of account. Significantly, even
China overseas lending by official entities is still 70% denominated in
dollars and only 10% in renminbi.
If, as we think,
that second approach is correct, no other money is positioned to
dislodge the dollar in the foreseeable future. Being a reserve currency
certainly brings privileges and power. It is also very demanding. Two
major requirements must be met, which no other country can do: a large
and liquid Treasury bond market (which Europe does not currently have)
and a fully and unconditionally open capital account (which China will
not have). Localised swap and barter agreements, such as developed by
China, can help but will not dispense of those two basic requirements.
(A columnist recently remarked that a credit line in renminbi is
financially equivalent to being fluent in Esperanto).
A quick look at other possible mentioned alternatives confirms that diagnosis:
- Currencies such as the Australian dollar are mentioned as possible reserve instruments.1 While fully open and accessible, the size of the Australian Treasury Bond market is only 2.5% of the US.
- There have been
recurrent attempts to make the Special Drawing Rights into a genuine
alternative to reserves – a course actively promoted by China in the
aftermath of the Global Crisis (Zhou 2009). They have largely stalled,
for reasons of size and accessibility (the possible use of Special
Drawing Rights is closely restricted by design).
- Some observers
stress the potentialities of cryptocurrencies, pointing to their role to
channel funds to Ukraine after the Russian invasion (Danielsson 2022).
However, they have no ability to process transactions on a large scale
(daily amounts mentioned in relation with Ukraine are in the tens of
millions of dollars). Despite some fascinating technological features,
cryptocurrencies are even further from having any significant role as
reserves. Managers are aware of the peculiarities of these money
systems. Their day-to-day functioning relies on the initiatives and
incentives of private operators, whose activity is purely voluntary and
profit-motivated. It is doubtful that they would entrust public reserves
to groups of ‘miners’ scattered all over the world, with a
non-negligible proportion having migrated to Kazakhstan after having
been prohibited to operate in China.
Globalisation and the demand for reserves
Sanctions may still
have significant longer-term effects – not on the composition, but on
the demand for reserves. The international monetary system may
ultimately adjust by moving to a new architecture, where financial
integration is reduced and, consequently, the need for reserves is
smaller.
Leaving aside the
reciprocal relation between the US and China – famously qualified by
Larry Summers as a “financial balance of terror” – it is useful to
consider the situation
of other emerging
countries. Around twenty countries have foreign exchange reserves above
$100 billion, most of them emerging economies. Borrowing from the
finance and climate literature, those countries clearly face a new ‘tail
risk’ of sanctions, with a very low probability but very high impact.
The same climate literature tells us that one cannot diversify against
those risks. The only way to buy insurance is to reduce one’s exposure.
In climate, it means bringing down CO2 emissions and
concentrations to low levels. For emerging economies, it means reducing
the need for (and dependence upon) foreign exchange reserves.
There has been a
constant increase in foreign exchange reserves until 2015 and a
plateauing since then. That evolution almost mirrors (with a lag of a
few years) the trends in gross cross-border capital flows and
international exposures, which expanded until 2010 and then stabilised
as a consequence of the Global Crisis.
Figure 1
a) Foreign exchange reserves
Source: ECB Economic Bulletin issue 7/2019.
b) Gross international assets and liabilities
Source: Adler and Garcia-Macia (2018).
This is not a
coincidence. With the exception of China, countries’ demand for reserves
is a direct result of their financial integration with the world.
Reserves are traditionally viewed as a tool for exchange rate
management. But they play a broader role. In many emerging economies,
the productive and financial sector is partially ‘dollarised’. As a
consequence of capital account liberalisation, both corporate and
financial institutions are able to borrow and lend in foreign currency.
Consequently, they may be facing maturity and liquidity mismatch in
dollars. Foreign reserves allow central banks in those countries to act
as lenders of last resort in foreign currency and protect domestic, as
well as external, financial stability. This is the fundamental reason
why reserves have, over the two last decades, expanded to levels that
are impossible to explain and rationalise by traditional metrics of
trade and financial openness.
Those policy choices
may well be reversed if and when reserves are carrying new risks.
Financial globalisation had essentially come to a halt well before the
invasion of Ukraine.
New forms of
sanctions, even if very rare, may lead to a further retreat and
segmentation of the world financial system (Harding 2022).
Ultimately,
sanctions, and their implications, reveal a basic, and forgotten, truth:
the movement towards greater financial globalisation has been
underpinned by a long-term commonality of purposes, standards and
understanding between countries. By supplying a reserve currency (and
benefiting from it), by augmenting it in crisis moments such as 2008 or
2020 by swap lines, the US has provided the world with a global public
good (Wolf 2022): widespread access to a safe asset, which can be used
as a buffer against financial shocks. Whether that equilibrium can be
preserved in a geopolitically divided world is a major question for the
future.
Vox
© VoxEU.org
Key
Hover over the blue highlighted
text to view the acronym meaning
Hover
over these icons for more information
Comments:
No Comments for this Article