In the
debate on reforming the EU, two needs emerge: securing fiscal space for
EMU countries, and ensuring that a more proactive fiscal policy remains
sustainable even when monetary policy reverts to normal (Buti and
Messori 2022).
Debt is at
record-high levels, but the EU's future challenges involve mostly public
infrastructural investments, with a trade-off between growth and
stability. Within this context, new fiscal rules and adequate forms of
debt management ought to be established jointly (D’Amico et al. 2022a,
2022b).
In a new paper
(Amato et al. 2022), we provide a quantitative simulation-based
assessment of the impact on prices and quantities of government debt in
the euro area of the working of a European Debt Agency (EDA), placed in
the current EU debate in Amato and Saraceno (2022).
The EDA operating model
The EDA collects
liquid funds on the market by issuing finite maturity bonds. When the
EDA begins its operations, member states stop issuing bonds. The agency
provides credit to member states to finance the repayment of their
maturing bonds as well as their primary budget deficit. This credit
facility takes the form of perpetual loans, priced using a risk-adjusted
unit cost differentiated according to the member states'
creditworthiness. EDA bonds are traded, while perpetual loans are not
traded,1 thus overcoming the difficulties of creating a
market for perpetuities. An adequate initial capital endowment and a
pricing policy aimed at achieving intertemporal financial equilibrium
would allow EDA to enjoy AAA status. The perpetual loans’ instalments
charged by the EDA would be calculated (1) by considering their
fundamental risk only, and (2) by including an amortisation quota of the loan itself.
But ‘perpetual’ does not mean ‘irredeemable’, since the EDA has the
possibility to reduce its balance sheet by drawing resources from its
reserves. By progressively raising a screen between markets and member
states, the EDA would eventually filter all member states’ liquidity and
refinancing risk, transforming all the euro area debt into a safe debt.
Nevertheless, since
the EDA would differentiate the price of its loans, the cost of debt for
each member state would depend on an assessment of its fundamental
risk, leaving each member state fully accountable for its fiscal policy decisions.
The operating model of the EDA is reflected in its balance sheet structure (see Figure 1, from Amato et al. 2021).
Figure 1 The EDA's balance sheet
A simulation exercise
We compute
historical series of the unit costs of loans with EDA for each member
state by applying the pricing framework for risky perpetual loans. We
assume that in the first period, initial capital is conferred to EDA
equal to the European Stability Mechanism (ESM) capital, reallocated
among member states according to the ESM weights. Reserve dynamics
depend then on the new inflows, annual payments on the perpetual loans,
and the remuneration of the stock. Reserves are remunerated by the ECB
at the rate paid by EDA on its bonds. Heterogeneous and independent
pricing of each country’s loans (which we label ‘idiomatic fundamental
pricing’) generates a total payment that is structurally higher than the
equilibrium payment computed by ‘pooling’ the debt of all member states
in the EDA. So, the EDA accumulates reserves in excess of the debt in
bonds that can be precisely attributed to each country. In the
simulation, the EDA absorbs all the member states’ outstanding bonds in a
decade.
Figure 2 shows the
historical series of these costs, recalculated for each member state
based on the counterfactual hypothesis that a debt agency has been
operational since 2002, and compares them with the cost for a
hypothetical country with the credit grade ‘next to default’ and the
yields of ten-year government bonds for Germany (lower yellow dotted
line) and Italy (upper green dotted line).
Figure 2
Ten-year government bond yields (Italy and Germany) and simulated
annual costs of perpetual loans (idiomatic costs) for selected member
states and a hypothetical (worst case) next to default country
These costs are
‘risk-sensitive’, but the idiomatic pricing of risk is very different
from the pricing observed in ten-year bond yields for Germany and Italy
during the sample. Importantly, idiomatic costs do not manifest
'diverging symmetries' in favour or against a particular member state,
and neither do they feature ‘excessive fluctuations’ in their government
debt market prices.
The simulation shows
that the low reduced volatility in loans prices has beneficial
consequences for the dynamics of member states’ debt.
The reserves
accumulated by the EDA under its pricing scheme will assure (together
with an initial capital endowment) the EDA intertemporal financial
equilibrium. We measure the required risk capital in terms of the number
of forbearance years of annual instalments allowed by each member
state’s total reserves. We use this wording because in ‘bad times’ when a
member state gets close to a credit risk class close to default,
reserves accumulated with EDA can be used by the member state to access a
‘forbearance facility’. During forbearance, reserves accumulated with
the EDA are used for servicing and restructuring debt and no new loans
are issued. The procedure gives the member state time and resources to
implement the necessary fiscal stabilisation policy smoothly.
During forbearance,
the use of reserves for debt repayment increases the debt of member
states with the EDA. Interestingly, the EDA will need to issue bonds on
the market to finance only the part of the member state’s total deficit
that is not paid by using their reserves with EDA. Debt repayment allows
member states to comply with fiscal rules. Also, notice that bonds
issued by the EDA grow faster than loans with the EDA outside
forbearance, while during forbearance, the opposite happens. The
existence of the EDA will facilitate smooth compliance with debt limits,
as set by the fiscal rules. These rules could be defined naturally by
targeting the ratio of bonds issued by EDA to GDP.
Figure 3 reports the number of forbearance years allowed by the EDA reserves.
Figure 3 Simulated EDA available capital measured in terms of payments ‘forbearance years’ for selected member states
Our counterfactual
simulations show that in the first years of EDA operations, while the
EDA is progressively acquiring member states’ maturing bonds, the
initial endowment plus the accumulated reserves give plenty of
forbearance capacity to all member states and reach a minimum just
between one and two forbearance periods, at the beginning of the fully
operational phase, which starts in 2011. Reserves then keep growing to
guarantee all member states a forbearance capacity of at least above
five years within the first ten years of the full operating period of
the EDA.
The case of the cost
for Greece is particularly interesting. This crisis was ignited by the
revelation, at the end of 2009, that Greece’s budget deficit was far
larger than the original estimates (the last revision brought it to
15.4% of GDP). Greece’s borrowing costs spiked as credit-rating agencies
downgraded the country’s sovereign debt to junk status in early 2010.
The costs that the EDA would have charged in these conditions show a
level and volatility that are not comparable with those of the observed
market prices on Greek ten-year bonds. On the occasion of the first wave
of the Greek crisis at the end of 2009, even if the available reserves
would not have allowed Greece to access forbearance, requiring
additional solvency capital to be provided externally,2 the
EDA would certainly have helped in containing contagion. However, on the
occasion of the second wave of the crisis in 2015, following the missed
payment of the IMF bailout in June 2015, a fully operational EDA would
have allowed over five years of forbearance to Greece, which would have
been very helpful to reduce the pain of fiscal stabilisation.
Conclusions: The benefits of an EDA
Establishing an EDA
would strongly reduce market instability and the cost of debt. This is
of course particularly appealing for high-debt countries and raises the
political economy issue of the feasibility of our proposal. Leandro and
Zettelmeyer (2018) provide a useful taxonomy of the characteristics that
a debt management tool should have to be politically viable and
efficient in maximising financial stability and minimising borrowing
costs. While noting that the EDA complies with all these requirements,
we argue that the EDA would benefit EMU core countries as well, and
therefore be beneficial for the single currency as a whole.
The EDA would allow a
smoother and more efficient working of financial markets and
enforcement of fiscal discipline, while also contributing to
streamlining the EMU macroeconomic policy governance. These objectives
will be achieved as EDA has the potential to:
(i) eliminate
liquidity and reprice risk, concentrating only on fundamental risk, thus
avoiding ‘bad equilibria’ (Blanchard and Pisani Ferry 2020);
(ii) establish a more efficient discipline mechanism through a fairer risk assessment;
(iii) structurally avoid mutualisation;
(iv) provide a truly
European safe asset, crucial for the economic and political positioning
of the EU in the new geopolitical context;
(v) systematically avoid juniority risk (see also Codogno and van den Noord 2019);
(vi) end the doom loop (a precondition for a full banking union and for normalising EMU bond markets);
(vii) allow the ECB to focus on its main mandate (Micossi 2021, D’Amico et al. 2022);
(viii) provide a
transparent, efficient division of labour within the commission by
separating the responsibilities for debt sustainability and debt
management and by providing a debt management institution that
facilitates the implementation of fiscal rules.
Our EDA proposal has
been guided by the three-fold need to (1) minimise borrowing costs for
member states, (2) stabilise sovereign debt markets, and (3) maximise
its acceptability in the EU political debate. This is why our proposal
is centred on the absence of debt mutualisation and continued
accountability of member states for their fiscal discipline. Good for
the EMU as a whole, the EDA would also be good for core countries. The
fact that the EDA would stabilise financial markets, help normalise
monetary policy and relieve the pressure on frugal countries (especially
Germany’s) bond markets contributes to making the proposal politically
viable for all.
References
Amato, M, E Belloni, P Falbo and L Gobbi (2021), “Europe, Public Debts, and Safe Assets: The Scope for a European Debt Agency”, Economia Politica 38(3): 823–61.
Amato, M, E Belloni, C Favero and L Gobbi(2022) “Creating a Safe Asset without Debt Mutualization: the Opportunity of a European Debt Agency”, CEPR Discussion Paper 17217
Amato, M and F
Saraceno (2022), “Squaring the Circle: How to Guarantee Fiscal Space and
Debt Sustainability with a European Debt Agency”, Baffi-Carefin Working
Papers 172 and Luiss School of Political Economy WP 1/2022.
Blanchard, O J, A Leandro and J Zettelmeyer (2021), “Redesigning EU Fiscal Rules: From Rules to Standards”, Economic Policy 36(106): 195–236.
Blanchard, O J and J Pisani-Ferry (2020), “Monetisation: Do Not Panic”, VoxEU.org, 10 April.
Buti M and M Messori (2022), "Reconciling the EU's Domestic Policy Agenda”, VoxEU.org, 11 April.
Codogno, L and P van den Noord (2019), “The Rationale for a Safe Asset and Fiscal Capacity for the Eurozone”, LEQS Paper 144.
D’Amico, L, F Giavazzi, V Guerrieri, G Lorenzoni and C-H Weymuller (2022a), “Revising the European Fiscal Framework, Part 1: Rules”, VoxEU.org, 14 January.
D’Amico, L, F Giavazzi, V Guerrieri, G Lorenzoni and C-H Weymuller (2022b), “Revising the European Fiscal Framework, Part 2: Debt Management”, VoxEU.org , 15 January.
Eichengreen B, A El-Ganainy, R Esteves and K J Mitchener (2021), In Defense of Public Debt, Oxford University Press.
Kelton, S (2020), The Deficit Myth. Modern Monetary Theory and the Birth of the People's Economy, New York: Public Affairs.
Leandro, A and J Zettelmeyer (2018), “The Search for a Euro Area Safe Asset”, PIIE Working Paper 3.
Micossi, S (2021), “On the Selling of Sovereigns Held by the ESCB to the ESM: A Revised Proposal”, CEPS Policy Insights 2021–17.
Endnotes
1 Financing member
state debt with perpetual loans explicitly recognises the difference
between government debt and household debt (Eichengreen 2021, Kelton
2020), leveraging on the perpetual nature of public debt (Amato and
Saraceno 2022) .
2 This is one of the
reasons why, during the first phase of its existence, the EDA could be
supplemented by a temporary scheme to unburden the ECB, for example as
suggested by Micossi (2021), by conferring the Covid debt to the ESM.