While the ECB is not allowed to monetise debt formally in the wake of the Covid-19 crisis, there seems to be some scope to do so, without fear of galloping inflation. It might even be needed to hit the inflation target.
I never thought one day I would actually
be discussing something a “serious economist” (an oxymoron?) would turn
away from in horror.
Mention Weimar Germany and Zimbabwe in
the same sentence and you know what I am talking about: monetary
financing of government debt.
For people not familiar with the concept
this is when a central bank prints new money and basically hands it
over to the government to spend, without the obligation to pay it back
one day. Plenty of proposals have been floating around over the past few
years and not all of them are actually feasible or permitted by the
European Treaties.
Nevertheless, it is still worth looking
at some of the alternatives and discussing the pros and cons in the wake
of the Covid-19 health crisis that has hit the eurozone. With debt
levels already very high in most member states lack the fiscal capacity
to tackle this new deflationary shock. So why not create the means
through the printing press?
Perpetuating debt holdings
The easiest proposals focus on the part
of sovereign bonds currently held by the European Central Bank (for
simplicity we will use the terms ECB and Eurosystem as substitutes).
Why not just eliminate this debt by
replacing these bonds with a zero-coupon perpetual? This would give
member states some breathing space and the capacity to spend more. But
not so fast. The central bank is actually owned by the government
(though there are a few cases where the ownership is mixed). And within
the Monetary Union, governments receive dividends from their national
banks, who in turn receive their share of the ECB’s profits.
A central bank’s profit derives from the
difference in interest income on the assets it holds and the interest
it pays on its liabilities. Banknotes by nature don’t carry an interest
rate. The profit the central bank makes on this is called seigniorage.
In normal times, a positive interest rate is paid on commercial bank
reserves, which are a large part of the central bank’s liabilities. But
now the ECB actually charges a negative interest rate on a big chunk of
bank reserves. Therefore, they also contribute to net interest income.
If the ECB exchanges interest-bearing debt on the asset side of its
balance sheet with a zero-coupon perpetual, then, of course, the central
bank’s profits will decline, which will result in lower dividends for
the governments in the future. For most central banks in the Eurosystem,
the dividends and taxes paid to the state are now around 0.1% to 0.3%
of GDP.
What most people don’t realise is that
there is already some mild form of debt monetisation. As a matter of
fact, in the current public sector purchase programme, bonds on the
ECB’s balance sheet that come to maturity are replaced with new bonds.
As in practice, the ECB will buy the new bonds that the governments are
raising to reimburse the central bank, it is pretty much as if the
central bank is holding the debt permanently on its balance sheet.
What’s more, the interest they pay to the central bank is, at the end of
the day, partially given back as a dividend. This is, of course, the
case as long as the interest paid on central bank liabilities is zero or
lower.
Graph 1: The money multiplier collapsed
So, in a nutshell, as long as the
central bank rolls over its stock of sovereign bonds, there is nearly no
difference with the situation where it replaces these bonds with a
zero-coupon perpetual: this part of the debt is not reimbursed and comes
at close to no interest cost. Admittedly, for the time being, there is
no commitment to keep them indefinitely on its balance sheet.
Further expand the balance sheet
Of course, the ECB could continue to
expand its balance sheet by further buying sovereign bonds and
refinancing these bond holdings forever. Actually, that is pretty much
what happened during and after the Second World War. Major central banks
substantially increased their balance sheets by purchasing government
debt and while the balance sheets were mostly reduced afterwards in
terms of GDP, they hardly ever did in nominal terms, as is explained here. In that way, it is believed that the Federal Reserve’s printing press financed about 15% of the war expenditures.
As the French President Emmanuel Macron
compared the current Covid-19 crisis to a war-like situation, a case
could be made for a permanent increase in the ECB’s balance sheet. The
trouble is that monetary financing isn’t actually allowed under the EU
treaties. Therefore, the ECB can use its balance sheet for monetary
purposes, but can never commit to keeping government debt on its books
indefinitely. The recent ruling of the German constitutional court is
likely to draw even more scrutiny to the central bank’s policy in this
regard. Of course, the ECB could do this by stealth. It doesn’t have to
say overtly that it will continue to refinance government debt, but in
practice, it could do so.
The only trouble here, a problem signalled by Adair Turner,
is that the central bank might be too credible in its denial of
monetary financing. In other words, the general public could believe
that the debt in the hands of the ECB will have to be repaid someday,
implying higher taxes in the future. That could lead to higher savings,
and consequently less growth now (a phenomenon called Ricardian
equivalence, if you want to impress your friends). So it is important that debt financing by the ECB is believed to be genuine in practice but non-existent in theory.
The hyperinflation sirens
But wouldn’t this further increase in the size of the balance sheet lead to more inflation?
We already had a strong increase in the
size of the balance sheet in previous years, not only in Europe but also
in the US and Japan. The argument goes that more of this would push
inflation through the roof. The reasoning behind this is to be found in
the quantitative theory of money: the more money in circulation, the
more inflation. What is lost in this reasoning, is that there is a
difference between the money on the balance sheet of the central bank
(base money, which equals notes in circulation and bank reserves) and
broad money in the hands of the general public.
The money multiplier, which is the ratio
of broad money to base money has actually collapsed. This is because
quantitative easing directly creates broad money and bank reserves in
similar amounts, but there is no extra money creation involved through
bank credits in the process (see here for a detailed explanation).
On top of that, the velocity of money, which measures the number of
times the stock of money is used to do purchases during a certain time
period, has also strongly declined. The latter is logical. As interest
rates on alternative assets are very low, people hold a larger chunk of
their wealth in the form of money, without actually using it to do
transactions. To illustrate these points you only have to look at what
happened in Japan over the last few decades. Since 1997, base money has
increased by a whopping 970%, while consumer prices over the same period
have basically remained unchanged. In other words, the increase in the
ECB’s balance sheet through the purchase of additional government bonds
doesn’t need to lead to significantly higher inflation, though of course
the amount of government bond purchases without causing higher
inflation, is not limitless either.
Graph 2: Declining velocity
Too low an inflation rate
You could even wonder if, at the end of
the day, a little bit more inflation is not what the eurozone needs.
Over the last 10 years, average inflation has been 1.3%, while average
core inflation and the average GDP deflator came out at 1.1%. Nominal
GDP growth, therefore, averaged a mere 2.5%. That is a worrying
phenomenon since the real burden of large debt levels remains high,
further depressing growth. With the current downturn creating a huge
negative GDP output gap, some extra stimulus seems warranted, without
immediately having to fear galloping inflation. And with short term
interest rates already negative, the only tool the central bank has left
to boost the economy further is balance sheet expansion. Since it is
not obvious how to determine the exact amount of permanent balance sheet
expansion, the central bank could announce a price level target in the
future (see e.g. Bernanke),
ideally one that allows for some correction of the inflation undershoot
that we experienced over the last decade. The establishment and
extension of the Pandemic Emergency Purchase Programme is already an
important step in this regard, though at this moment the programme is
still labelled as temporary.
Monetary dominance
The final question is whether the ECB,
by monetising part of the fiscal expansion, would become hostage to the
fiscal authorities. Fiscal authorities might want to prevent an interest
rate increase because this would implicitly increase the cost on the
debt held by the central bank (it would reduce the central bank’s
interest income and thereby the dividends paid out to the governments),
while at the same time, new debt would also have to be issued at a
higher interest rate. And if the fiscal expansion to fight Covid-19 is
now accommodated by the central bank, why couldn’t the same thing be
done to finance the green agenda?
In that way, fiscal policy would become
dominant, a thesis advanced by the proponents of Modern Monetary Theory:
governments can spend newly created money as long as there is no full
employment. Only when the situation of full employment is reached do
governments have to hit the (tax) brakes to avoid inflation. However,
past experiences of the central bank’s monetary policy being
subordinated to fiscal policy did not end well.
A politician who needs to get re-elected
is generally not the one who will “take away the punch bowl just as the
party gets going”. That is basically the reason why most industrial
countries have opted for an independent central bank that has to
maintain the purchasing power of money in the longer run. But even when
maintaining the dominance of monetary policy over fiscal policy, we
believe that today, there is some scope to accommodate fiscal expansion
by a further increase in the ECB’s balance sheet, without having to fear
inflation going through the roof. At the end of the day, it might even
be needed to bring inflation back to close to, but below 2%.
About the author
Peter Vanden Houte is
Chief Economist of ING Belgium, Luxembourg. He has has been working with
ING in various research functions for more than 20 years. He is also
vice-chairman of the “economic commission” at the Belgian Employers
Federation.
SUERF
© SUERF
Key
Hover over the blue highlighted
text to view the acronym meaning
Hover
over these icons for more information
Comments:
No Comments for this Article