Almost two and a half years ago, we expressed on these columns some fears about the preparatory work for the reform of the ESM, and in particular on the Franco-German Meseberg declaration, which provided the reference framework for the reform then submitted to the Euro summit on June 28, 2018.
Our
perplexities were only marginally motivated by the amendments to the text about
to be made.
The most
significant risk was that even the slightest underlining of certain concepts
could give rise to a new ‘Deauville effect’. At the Deauville summit in
November 2010, German Chancellor Angela Merkel and the then French President
Nicolas Sarkozy introduced the concept of ‘Private Sector Involvement’ (PSI),
i.e. the restructuring of public securities held by private individuals. That
statement, which concerned the Greek case only, had destabilising effects on
many Eurozone countries, including Italy.
Our concern was
that some clauses of the reform could have similar effects. In particular, our
fears and that of many other economists were motivated by three points, which
are evident in the Meseberg declaration and much more nuanced in the text of
the reform: the repetition of the concept of PSI, albeit confined to
exceptional cases; the introduction of the so-called ‘single limb’ Collective
Action Clauses that facilitate debt restructuring; and finally the balance of
powers between the Commission and the ESM in favour of the latter which is an
intergovernmental body.
Our fears at the
time proved unfounded. Neither the Meseberg declaration, nor the subsequent
publication of the reform text in July 2019, nor the approval of the text by
the Eurogroup on November 7, 2019, had adverse effects in financial markets.
It may be that
our fears were excessive, or it may be that the decisions of the ECB intervened
in the meantime have had the effect of avoiding tensions in financial markets.
It may also be that the yield spread on the Italian debt was already considered
sufficiently high by financial markets, due to the imprudent declarations and
some concrete actions by the yellow-green government.
Indeed, we would
have preferred some points of the reform to be formulated differently, notably
to emphasise the need for a careful cost-benefit analysis of the PSI in the
specific conditions of each country. However, we believe that if the Italian
Parliament today commits to reject the reform of the ESM treaty, the approval
of which requires the unanimity of the Member States, it would cause serious
damage to Italy. It would jeopardise good relations with other European
countries, none of which seem to have doubts about the reform. It would
preclude bringing forward the ‘common backstop’ for the Single Resolution Fund,
an essential element of the banking union, which is scheduled for 2022. It
would put at risk the negotiations ― already complicated ― on the Next
Generation EU plan, of which Italy is the main beneficiary country.
Someone said, to
motivate opposition to the reform, that it would serve to force Italians to
finance the bailout of German banks. It is a very bizarre theory, as the
revision of the treaty allows the ESM to finance any shortcomings of the Single
Resolution Fund (SRF) for banks without touching the pockets of taxpayers. With
the possible ramifications of the current crisis in the banking sector, this
safety net is no small feat.
It is also not
true that the ESM is the ‘old Europe’, as some say. In the future, country
assistance programmes will be managed by the Commission-ESM tandem. It is the
overcoming of the so-called Troika (Commission, IMF, ECB). Any future problems
will be managed ‘internally’ according to the community approach, with the
Commission being the only guarantor of compliance with European rules. It is a
concrete manifestation of the solidarity of low-debt countries towards others;
in fact, the most significant resistance in the past came from Northern
countries.
As obvious as it
may be, the key point that critics seem to overlook is that any choice to go to
the ESM in case of need is entirely in the hands of the country concerned.
Therefore, the ESM is only an important additional option. The mere fact that
the ESM exists has the effect of discouraging possible pressures in financial
markets. This is because it can provide the country with the ammunition
necessary to counter them and because it is the gateway to the Outright
Monetary Transactions (OMT), i.e. ECB’s intervention which in principle could
be unlimited.
Finally, the ESM
reform is different from the request for a line of credit under the so-called
‘healthcare ESM’ (Pandemic Crisis Support), with conditionality limited to the
use of resources for health expenditure, which has been talked about a lot in
Italy. Therefore, Italy should think about it a thousand times before rejecting
the reform.
Key
Hover over the blue highlighted
text to view the acronym meaning
Hover
over these icons for more information
Comments:
No Comments for this Article