Those rules are built on a series of debatable conceptions about public debt and the role played by the state. This paper focuses on debunking eight often-espoused conceptions.
Europe faces serious environmental, economic and social challenges
that require a rethink on public intervention. Not free to do as they
wish, European governments de- vise fiscal and socio-economic policies
constrained by a self-imposed maze of economic governance rules.
MYTH 1 – DEBT OVERLOAD
The public debate overly relies on arbitrary debt-to-GDP thresholds to gauge debt sustainability,
overlooking true explanatory factors. Those include evolution of
government revenue, interest rate, debt composition (i.e. currency
denomination, ownership, maturity structure), differential between
interest and growth rates and the building up of fiscal risks. Interest
payment-to-public revenue (flow-to-flow) seems a more meaningful proxy
indicator of debt sustainability than debt-to-GDP (stock-to-flow).
MYTH 2 – INFLATION
A growing concern centres on inflation possibly returning, driving up
interest rates, which would render debt unsustainable. Meanwhile,
analysis shows a different story: a situation where this risk is not the
most pressing one as inflation and interest rates are driven by
structural factors unlikely to change in the near future. Temporary, measured inflation can be expected in the short-run, not a sustained rise of inflation and interest rates.
MYTH 3 – FUTURE BURDEN
Public debt often gets framed as an unfair burden on future
generations. The “intergenerational equity” story overplays the
liability trope around debt while overlooking three fundamental
arguments. First, intergenerational equity commands investment that builds a resilient and sustainable world.
Without that investment, governments will fall short when trying to
provide for the most basic needs of future generations. Investment costs
will weigh less on future generations’ shoulders than the cost of
failing to do so. Second, debt provides a legitimate way of spreading costs across all benefiting generations
when it provides financing for investments in education, research,
innovation, sustainable and resilient infrastructures and productive ca-
pacities. Third, the current ultra-low interest rate environment provides the opportunity to lock-in low, long funding costs,
which relieve the debt burden for future generations. Intergenerational
equity commands to discern debt sustain- ability as intertwined with
the sustainability of the world. In a context where there can be no such
thing as sustainable debt without a sustainable world, Europe must
shift from an excessive focus on public spending quantity to a pledge to
ensure its quality.
MYTH 4 – CROWDING OUT EFFECT
Public investment often gets brushed off under the argument that it
would crowd out more productive private investment. In fact, this
portrait overlooks three core arguments. First, a crowding-out effect
cannot exist in the current world-wide environment of excess liquidity
and savings. Second, public goods provision, resilience building, and
climate change mitigation requires public money, as related investments
cannot be expected to be solely privately financed. Third, quality
public investments can boost and steer the economy towards socially
desirable goals. Captured by the fiscal multiplier, this crowding in
effect proves particularly strong during recessions and low interest
rate periods. Far from being antagonistic, public and private investments must be seen for what they are: namely complementary.
MYTH 5 – SPENDTHRIFTS
EU countries with comparatively high stocks of government debt to
fellow Member States often get accused of living “beyond their means”. A
closer look shows a more nuanced picture. While no evidence exists
showing excessive social spending or lower working hours, significant
shares of public debt appear to be a legacy from unexpected events such
as the financial crisis of 2007-2009 or the current Covid-19 pandemic.
In a number of cases, high levels of public indebtedness embody the
legacy from the high interest rates that prevailed in the 1980s and
1990s and not from supposedly reckless fiscal policies conducted since
then. Italy provides a case, for instance, as it suffered an average
yield on 10-year govern- ment bonds of 14% between 1980 and 1993, with a
peak surpassing 20% in 1982, and reached continuous primary surpluses
during the recent decades.
MYTH 6 – BUDGET SURPLUS ANALOGY
Building on the household analogy, public budget surplus is often
presented as a necessity to repay debts and build “fiscal space”. This
debate reveals two main flaws: First, a public budget surplus means the
government takes from society more than it gives to society. Seeking budget surpluses proves counterproductive when interest rates fall below growth rate and when economic depression hits,
and is always of secondary importance in comparison with investing to
build a sustainable and resilient society – as evidenced by the
importance of sustainability-related fiscal risks. Second, intra-EU trade imbalances continue to hamper the prospects for every Member State to run concomitant budget surpluses. Rather than trimming back spending to comply with arbitrary numerical fiscal rules, the European Union and its Member States should focus on investments that contribute to building a sustainable and resilient economy,
pouncing on the current rock-bottom interest rate environment to lower
fiscal risks, extend debt maturities and bring down debt servicing
costs. Protecting public budgets better from swings in market sentiment
requires monetary policy that ensures permanent market access for
sovereigns at favourable conditions as well as a stronger “lender of
last resort”. Orderly sovereign debt restructuring should be facilitated
when debt becomes unsustainable. Lastly, policy should address intra-EU
trade imbalances.
MYTH 7 – FENCED IN RULES
EU fiscal rules are presented as a package of sound limits designed
to eschew the deficit bias of politicians. Meanwhile, the chosen fiscal
limits lack economic justification: while the 60% debt-to-GDP limit was
only a rough average of the then 12 EU countries, the 3% deficit limit
is the economically unjustified heritage of its prior usage in France. Whilst
the “debt-to-GDP” ratio suffers important conceptual flaws – such as
non-commensurability and time-inconsistency – debt sustainability
requires more than reaching a specific threshold.
MYTH 8 – AMPLE WRIGGLE ROOM
European fiscal rules usually get depicted as flexible enough. In fact, flexibility
is sparse and the rules dampen growth and employment while holding back
Europe from reaching its environmental and social goals.
Reforms must aim to improve quality of spending, take context better
into account and prioritise long-term social and environmental
sustainability over arbitrary fiscal constraints.
Finance Watch
Key
Hover over the blue highlighted
text to view the acronym meaning
Hover
over these icons for more information
Comments:
No Comments for this Article