Follow Us

Follow us on Twitter  Follow us on LinkedIn
 

03 October 2022

CEPR/Vox's Buti/Messorri: A central fiscal capacity to tackle stagflation


In the past year, there have been many calls for a permanent central fiscal capacity at the EU or euro area level. This column argues that a European central fiscal capacity would improve policy efficiency by focusing on stabilisation in the event of demand shocks and on boosting potential output in the event of supply shocks.

  The provision of European public goods appears to be the most promising avenue to tackle the present stagflationary threats. The need to calibrate the central interventions in relation to the typology of shocks calls for a reform of the EU institutional set up, including the creation of a European Minister for Economic Affairs.

Editors' note: This column is a lead commentary in the VoxEU debate on euro area reform.


NextGenerationEU (NGEU) is the centralised fiscal initiative agreed by the EU in 2020 to ‘build back better’ after the pandemic; and the ‘Fit-for-55’ indicates the road that the EU should follow to reach the sustainable economic and social development that is one of the main aims of a central fiscal capacity. The EU’s long-term economic potential would be improved if the member states were able to effectively meet the NGEU and Fit-for-55 requirements, also through the most recent REPowerEU recommendations.

In the past year, several academic papers have called for the setting up of a permanent central fiscal capacity at the EU or euro area level (e.g. Beetsma et al. 2021, Maduro et al. 2021, Romanelli et al. 2022). During the public consultation on the review of the EU economic governance by the Commission, the ECB, IMF and OECD made similar proposals.  In a previous paper (Buti and Messori 2021), we outlined that – in principle – a central fiscal capacity could focus on three functions: cyclical stabilisation, support for the implementation of national structural reforms and investment, and the supply of European public goods (EPGs). Table 1 sketches out the main goals, the operational targets, and the key features of these three options.


Table 1 Central fiscal capacity: Three options

Table 1 Central fiscal capacity: Three options

Source: authors’ elaborations

Creating a central stabilisation capacity would be the most rational choice for the completion of the euro area’s economic governance framework. It would complement the response of the ECB and of national fiscal policies to symmetric and country-specific demand shocks. The most cumbersome political issue is moral hazard: if the national governments anticipated the support by a central fiscal instrument in case of negative shocks, they would have less incentive to create national fiscal room for manoeuvre in periods of strong growth. This would lead to a ratcheting up of public debt and would increase the risk of that form of fiscal dominance that characterised the euro area in the period 2014–2018. The observed lack of fiscal adjustments during ‘good times’ strengthened this argument (e.g. European Commission, 2019). Hence, the political feasibility of the first option will remain untested unless there is a significant improvement in cooperation (and trust) between the EU’s member states.

The second option – that is, setting up conditional transfers to the EU member states to support national reforms and investment – would build on NGEU arrangements and be akin to de facto reviving the proposal of ‘contractual arrangements’ made by Herman van Rompuy in mid-2013 when he was at the helm of the European Council. The proposal was rejected by the majority of the EU’s member states at the end of that same year: the Northern countries refused permanent transfers, whilst the Southern countries resented an intrusive role of the European authorities in their domestic policy choices. Under the pressure of the pandemic shock, NGEU overcame those objections by its temporary nature.

A third option is to use the central fiscal capacity to step up the supply of EPGs. Whilst NGEU represented a breakthrough and a fundamental institutional innovation, its ‘European added value’ in its final design was lower than in the initial proposal by the Commission. As we pointed out in an earlier paper (Buti and Messori 2020, see also Pisani Ferry 2020), in the agreement on NGEU reached at the European Council in July 2020, the non-allocated part of its main programme (the Recovery and Resilience Facility, or RRF) was substantially reduced in favour of transfers to member states. Conversely, the supply of ‘pure’ European public goods (as dubbed by Buti and Papaconstantinou 2022) – such as a European security system, the joint public procurement of vaccines, investment in hydrogen energy, the construction of a European telecommunication network, or the joint production of semiconductors – cannot be satisfied by the simple aggregation of national public goods...

more at CEPR/Vox



© CEPR - Centre for Economic Policy Research


< Next Previous >
Key
 Hover over the blue highlighted text to view the acronym meaning
Hover over these icons for more information



Add new comment