ICAEW publishes report calling for changes to disclosure rules

16 December 2013

ICAEW has published a report by its Financial Reporting Faculty calling for urgent reform to the regulation of financial reporting disclosures, saying that if the system is not changed quickly, the current situation will get worse as the volume of irrelevant material increases.

"Financial Reporting Disclosures: Market and Regulatory Failures" argues that the current disclosure overload is to a large degree an outcome of the regulatory framework. At the same time, the report also states that this framework is a response to failures in the market for financial reporting information. And both market and regulatory failures in part reflect the inherent limitations of financial reporting.

There is a conflict between regulation and standardisation of financial reporting disclosures on the one hand and the diversity of firms and user needs on the other. This conflict underlies some of the most important concerns about financial reporting disclosures.

Overall, it is a predictable result of the present regulatory system that it will lead to a proportion of disclosures that are irrelevant to particular firms and to particular users, and that, if it is left unchanged, the volume of irrelevant disclosures is likely to grow.

There are broadly four ways in which the regulatory causes of the problem can be tackled: reform the process for setting disclosure requirements; change the requirements themselves; change the way in which the requirements are implemented; and place more reliance on non-regulatory solutions.

Reforming the process for setting disclosure requirements

1. The standard-setting process should be reformed so as to give more weight to the views of equity shareholders who as owners meet the costs of disclosure requirements.

There is a view that the standard-setting process focuses unduly on the needs of a small group of users who have an apparently limitless appetite for information, but who do not bear the costs of producing it. If standard-setters were to give more weight to the interests of those who ultimately meet the costs of their decisions, this would give greater legitimacy to the requirements that they impose.

2. Standard-setters should establish a framework to provide a structure for setting disclosure requirements. This should ensure that disclosures are only required when they are needed and that they are properly organised, and should recognise that disclosure requirements reflect a balancing of interests, rather than an unqualified commitment to transparency. The framework should form part of the conceptual framework for financial reporting.

3. To the extent that firms comply with disclosure requirements even though the resulting information is immaterial, standard-setters should reflect this in deciding whether disclosure requirements are proportionate. If standard-setters are able to assume that their disclosure requirements only lead to the disclosure of material information, when in fact they lead to a lot of immaterial disclosures as well, their calculations of the costs and benefits of disclosure requirements will be unrealistic.

Changing the disclosure requirements

4. Disclosure requirements should allow firms to report separate information sets to different types of users. At present the disclosure system fails to distinguish between the very different needs of the various users of financial reporting information. While some users may be happy with lengthy disclosures, the majority are sent information that is far longer and more complex than they can make use of. The information set for most users could be short and, beyond a minimal common core, decided by each firm to reflect its own particular circumstances. Regulation of disclosures in the common core should itself be minimal so as to allow for effective communication. Both information sets should be online and available for anyone who wants to access them.

5. Standard-setters should regularly review their disclosure requirements to weed out unnecessary disclosures. The IASB’s first such review should be initiated as soon as it has finalised the conceptual framework on disclosure.

Changing the way disclosure requirements are implemented

6. To reduce the incentives to provide immaterial disclosures, enforcement agencies should clarify that they will not take action against firms that omit immaterial disclosures, and they should encourage firms to omit immaterial disclosures. As international firms make disclosures in more than one jurisdiction, this would require a common approach among enforcement agencies internationally.

7. Auditors should refrain from encouraging firms to make immaterial disclosures and should encourage them to omit immaterial disclosures.

8. Once enforcement agencies and auditors have reformed their approach to materiality, firms should cut out disclosures that are clearly immaterial.

Placing more reliance on non-regulatory solutions

9. Preparers and users should engage directly to discuss voluntary public disclosure of information that is not currently provided, rather than rely entirely on standard-setters to introduce new disclosure requirements.

Press release

Short briefing paper

Full report


© ICAEW - Institute of Chartered Accountants in England and Wales