|
What do you dislike so much about the bond purchase [programme]?
First, the programme entails a willingness to make huge and, in principle, unlimited use of the central bank balance sheet to reallocate insolvency risks among taxpayers in individual countries. In a monetary union with 17 sovereign Member States, such decisions should be reserved for democratically elected parliaments. Furthermore, as a central bank, we should keep ourselves at a safe distance from monetary financing of governments. Finally, moral hazard comes into play – the risk that governments’ willingness to reform will wane if, through the measures we take, we reduce the pressure on them to act.
Will the ECB tighten the monetary reins again – even if this means jeopardising financial stability?
Our primary responsibility is to ensure price stability. If inflation risks were to intensify, we would have to act. Obviously, this course of action may have feedback effects on financial stability. Some governments appear to be financing themselves on an increasingly short-term basis. This means that their budget position is more closely tied to current short-term interest rates. But the fact that the fiscal policymakers have manoeuvred themselves into this dependency cannot mean that the monetary policymakers should go easier on their primary task of ensuring price stability.
So, to be clear: if the ECB has to raise interest rates to combat inflation, it will drive governments so far into deficit that the sovereign debt crisis will start up all over again.
Budgetary positions should see fundamental improvement as a result of the reforms. But if some sovereigns should find it hard to access the capital markets, then the ESM would be there as the financial assistance mechanism which was created for just this purpose. However, in principle countries need to arrange their affairs in such a way that they can deal with the single monetary policy without assistance. Competitive economic structures and sound government finances are preconditions for a stable monetary union. Monetary policy cannot create those preconditions. That would be asking too much of it. This was entirely clear when monetary union was launched.
A lesson that we have had to learn is that monetary union is not working because the differences in competitiveness and economic strength are so great. And then the politicians come along and say: we just need to cooperate more closely, then it will work. But no one wants common taxation and economic policies let alone a joint fiscal policy.
I share your assessment that there is not much political will or public support for surrendering national sovereignty. In fact, it is often lowest in those countries that are the loudest in calling for greater shared liability. So I see no great leap towards fiscal union. But that means sticking to what we agreed when monetary union was set up: the principles enshrined in the Maastricht Treaty, according to which each member state is responsible for itself. In any case, we should steer clear of the ever greater mutualisation of risks if this does not also involve surrendering national sovereignty – because if liability and control are not in step, the basis for monetary union will be undermined.
Will the ECB become a superpower if, from 2014 onwards, it has responsibility not just for price stability but also for supervising Europe's 200 largest banks?
Let me say first of all that we at the Bundesbank regard banking union in principle as a very important and appropriate step in the process of strengthening the future institutional framework of monetary union. The purpose, amongst other things, is to put in place effective supervision and a strict regulatory framework which will loosen the current close links between the risks arising in a country's public finances and the health of its banking system. When important decisions like this are being made, careful planning should take priority over speed. In our view it is particularly important to prevent conflicts of interest between banking supervision and monetary policy. I do not regard this issue as having been satisfactorily resolved yet.
Can the planned mediation panel resolve the problem?
There are to be three bodies looking after banking supervision in future, starting with the Supervisory Board, which will operate within the ECB and prepare decisions for the ECB Governing Council. The Governing Council will only be able to simply reject or accept these decision-making proposals – it will not be able to amend them. I find this curious: if I am to bear political responsibility, I have to be able to shape the decisions. But that is not all: if the ECB Governing Council rejects a proposal from the Supervisory Board, and one country does not agree with this decision, then a third body comes into play – the mediation panel. This mediation panel then decides by simple majority. But the panel’s decisions cannot be binding: under the relevant EU legislation the ECB Governing Council has to have the final say.
Sounds like a complex construct that makes little sense. Why are things being done this way?
It is an attempt, using a legal basis which is not really suitable, to erect a Chinese wall between monetary policy and supervisory tasks. But it is more like a Japanese wall or a room-divider. All this leads to is a very complex system in which the lines of responsibility are blurred. In my view, it would be preferable to amend the EU treaties with a view to putting in place robust separation between monetary policy and supervisory decision-making structures.
Isn’t such a separation at the ECB just theoretical anyway? What is the use of a Chinese wall on floors five to twelve, if the monetary policymakers and bank supervisors have lunch together in the same canteen?
The exchange of opinions between specialists and the bundling of expertise are wholly desirable. That is why the Bundesbank is part of the German banking supervisory framework. The problem does not arise potentially until one body is making binding decisions for two areas of responsibility. In this respect, Germany’s dual system has its advantages, in that the Bundesbank undertakes ongoing supervision while BaFin in Bonn makes sovereign decisions.
So you do not want the ECB to decide that a bank should be wound up.
This bundling of responsibilities has been decided on for the time being, we now need to minimise conflicts of interest. As a organisation which is already up and running, the ECB could act as a midwife for the supervisory set-up. But I would like the current construct, in which final responsibility lies with the ECB Governing Council, to be no more than a transitional solution. Banking supervision should be transferred to an entirely independent body to make the decisions. This is the only way that doubts about the independence of the ECB Governing Council in its monetary policy decisions can be dispelled.
What will happen if the European supervisors find that a bank requires additional capital?
Then the bank will have to obtain the capital. If it is not able to do so, it will have to be restructured or wound up. It is for such cases that we need a recovery and resolution mechanism at European level financed by the banks. Such a mechanism has to ensure that liability is borne first by the banks’ shareholders, then by other creditors, then by a fund financed by the banks, and only lastly and exceptionally by taxpayers. We should create this mechanism swiftly, otherwise the banking union will be incomplete. And even then, the banking union must not act as a cover for shifting responsibility for problematic legacy assets in individual countries to the European level. The problematic assets which are currently stuck on bank balance sheets stem from unhealthy developments at national level and the mistakes of national supervisors, and should therefore be borne by the owners and creditors of the relevant banks or by taxpayers in the country concerned.
Does it make sense for the ECB to have responsibility only for banks with total assets of €30 billion and above?
It is certainly a clear criterion which enables those banks subject to single supervision to be separated out easily from the others. However, a somewhat smaller number of banks could have been covered than the 200 which are planned. After all, according to the plans, the ECB can extend its supervision to smaller institutions anyway if it deems this necessary.
The compromise is a first step towards a European banking union. Is the next step a joint deposit insurance scheme, in which German savers will be liable for Spanish banks?
No. As I mentioned, the next step is a recovery and resolution mechanism. I do not think a deposit insurance scheme is necessary. Adding a further element of liability would require considerably greater powers of intervention in member states' fiscal and economic policies.
Is it not unfair that banks have higher refinancing costs just because they come from a country with unsound government finances?
Just as fair or unfair as higher car insurance premiums if you live in a region with a large number of accidents. The reality is that we have differing government solvency risks. The fact that sovereign solvency and national economic performance are also reflected in banks’ balance sheets and refinancing costs is not a dysfunction, it is plain logic. The conclusion we draw from this must not be that these risks need to be negated or spread across the whole of Europe, but that states need to be forced to stick to the rules, to ensure they have sound finances and to restore their economy’s competitiveness. It is the causes of the solvency spreads that need to be tackled, not the symptoms which are reflected in banks’ balance sheets.
You have often been a lone voice anyway in many of the decisions made by the ECB Governing Council. Why have you not been able to make your views prevail in the past?
In such a fundamental debate about the role of monetary policy, a number of factors play a role, one of which is doubtless the national traditions and history that shape each and every one of us. But nor can one always escape the influence of the economic situation in one's own country. It makes a difference whether 50 per cent of young people are out of work back home or whether there is almost full employment. However, I do not have the feeling that my arguments are not coming across in the discussions. Many of my concerns are shared by colleagues on the Governing Council.
You are the only one voting against!
That is far from being true of all decisions. However, when it comes to measures which might be seen as monetary financing of governments, I believe it is particularly important to take a principled stand. But even then the majority on the Governing Council factors into its decisions concerns which I have put forward.
And if you want to mop up the flood of money, the others say: we would rather have five per cent inflation than five per cent unemployment?
You seem to be suggesting that my colleagues are not sticking to our mandate. We all feel duty-bound to price stability. And according to our most recent projections, the inflation rate is likely to fall back to below 2 per cent in the next two years. To ensure continuing price stability thereafter, we will have to tighten up the ultra-loose monetary policy in good time. But no one can say at the moment when that will be.