VoxEU: How to reconcile risk sharing and market discipline in the euro area

17 January 2018

This column proposes six reforms which, if delivered as a package, would improve the euro area’s financial stability, political cohesion, and potential for delivering prosperity to its citizens, all while addressing the priorities and concerns of participating countries.

The deadlock over euro area reform

The members of the euro area are deeply divided on how to address these problems. Some argue for more flexible rules and better stabilisation and risk-sharing instruments at the euro area level, such as common budgetary mechanisms (or even fiscal union) to support countries in trouble. Others would like to see tougher rules and stronger incentives to induce prudent policies at the national level, while rejecting any additional risk sharing. One side would like to rule out sovereign-debt restructuring as a tool for overcoming deep debt crises, while the other argues that market discipline is indispensable for fiscal responsibility, and ultimately for financial stability. The seeming irreconcilability of these positions has produced a deadlock over euro area reform.

We believe that the choice between more risk sharing and better incentives is a false alternative, for three reasons. First, a robust financial architecture requires instruments for both crisis prevention (good incentives) and crisis mitigation (since risks remain even with the best incentives). Second, risk-sharing mechanisms can be designed in a way that mitigates or even removes the risk of moral hazard. Third, well-designed risk-sharing and stabilisation instruments are in fact necessary for effective discipline. In particular, the no bailout rule will lack credibility if its implementation leads to chaos, contagion, and the threat of euro area break-up – as euro area members experienced in 2010-12 and again during the 2015 Greek aftershock. Well-designed risk-sharing arrangements and improved incentives, in the form of both better rules and more market discipline, should hence be viewed as complements not substitutes.

Six areas for reform

Achieving this complementarity, however, is not straightforward in practice. It calls for stabilisation and insurance mechanisms that are both effective and do not give rise to permanent transfers. It also requires a reformed institutional framework. In a new CEPR Policy Insight (Bénassy-Quéré et al. 2017), we outline six main areas of reform to the European financial, fiscal, and institutional architecture that would meet these aims.

First, breaking the vicious circle between banks and sovereigns through the coordinated introduction of sovereign concentration charges for banks and a common deposit insurance. The former would require banks to post more capital if debt owed by a single sovereign creditor – typically the home country – exceeds a certain proportion of their capital, incentivising the diversification of banks’ portfolios of government securities. The latter would protect all insured euro area depositors equally, irrespective of the country and its situation when the insurance is triggered. Incentives for prudent policies at the national level would be maintained by pricing country-specific risk in the calculation of insurance premiums, and through a reinsurance approach – common funds could be tapped only after ‘national compartments’ have been exhausted.  

At the same time, mechanisms to bail in creditors of failing banks need to be strengthened, supervisory pressure to reduce existing non-performing loans needs to increase (including on smaller banks), and bank regulatory standards should be tightened and further harmonised. To give capital markets union a push, the European Securities and Markets Authority (ESMA) should receive wider authority over an increasing range of market segments, and its governance should be reformed accordingly. Together, these measures would decisively reduce the correlation between bank and sovereign risk and pave the way for a cross-border integration of banking and capital markets.

Second, replacing the current system of fiscal rules focused on the ‘structural deficit’ by a simple expenditure rule guided by a long-term debt reduction target. The present rules both lack flexibility in bad times and teeth in good times. They are also complex and hard to enforce, exposing the European Commission to criticism from both sides.  They should be replaced by the principle that government expenditure must not grow faster than long-term nominal output, and should grow at a slower pace in countries that need to reduce their debt-to-GDP ratios. A rule of this type is both less error-prone than the present rules and more effective in stabilising economic cycles, since cyclical changes in revenue do not need to be offset by changes in expenditure. 

Monitoring compliance with the fiscal rule should be devolved to independent national fiscal watchdogs, supervised by an independent euro area-level institution, as elaborated below. Governments that violate the rule would be required to finance excess spending using junior (‘accountability’) bonds whose maturity would be automatically extended in the event of an ESM programme (the status of the existing debt stock would remain unaffected). The real-time market pressure associated with the need to issue such bonds would be far more credible than the present threats of fines, which have never been enforced. And the cost at which these junior sovereign bonds are issued will depend on the credibility of government policies to tackle fiscal problems in the future.

Third, creating the economic, legal and institutional underpinnings for orderly sovereign-debt restructuring of countries whose solvency cannot be restored through conditional crisis lending. First and foremost, this requires reducing the economic and financial disruptions from debt restructuring – by reducing the exposure of banks to individual sovereigns, as described above, and by creating better stabilisation tools and a euro area safe asset, as described below. In addition, orderly and credible debt restructuring requires legal mechanisms that protect sovereigns from creditors that attempt to ‘hold out’ for full repayment, and ESM policies and procedures that provide an effective commitment not to bail out countries with unsustainable debts.

When introducing such policies, it is essential that they do not give rise to instability in debt markets. For this reason, we do not advocate a policy that would require automatic haircuts or maturity extensions of all maturing debt in the event of an ESM programme. Furthermore, tougher ESM lending policies and sovereign concentration charges for banks should be:

Fourth, creating a euro area fund, financed by national contributions, that helps participating member countries absorb large economic disruptions. Since small fluctuations can be offset through national fiscal policies, pay-outs would be triggered only if employment falls below (or unemployment rises above) a pre-set level. To ensure that the system does not lead to permanent transfers, national contributions would be higher for countries that are more likely to draw on the fund, and revised based on ongoing experience. This system would maintain good incentives through three mechanisms: ‘first losses’ would continue to be borne at national level, participation in the scheme would depend on compliance with fiscal rules and the European semester, and higher drawings would lead to higher national contributions.

Fifth, an initiative to create a synthetic euro area safe asset that would offer investors an alternative to national sovereign bonds. ‘Safety’ could be created through a combination of diversification and seniority; for example, financial intermediaries would purchase a standardised diversified portfolio of sovereign bonds and use this as collateral for a security issued in several tranches. Introducing such assets in parallel with a regulation on limiting sovereign concentration risk would further help avoid disruptive shifts in the demand for euro area sovereign bonds, and hence contribute to financial stability. Risks associated with the introduction of such assets must be mitigated both through careful design and by completing a test phase before the generation of such assets is ‘scaled up’.

Sixth, reforming the euro area institutional architecture. We propose two main reforms. The first is an improvement of the institutional surveillance apparatus. The role of the watchdog (‘prosecutor’) should be separated from that of the political decision-maker (‘judge’) by creating an independent fiscal watchdog within the European Commission (for example, a special Commissioner) or, alternatively, by moving the watchdog role outside the Commission (though this would require an overhaul of the treaties). At the same time, the Eurogroup presidency role (judge) could be assigned to the Commission, following the template of the High Representative of the Union for Foreign Affairs.

In addition, the policy responsibility for conditional crisis lending should be fully assigned to a reformed ESM, with an appropriate accountability structure. The latter should include a layer of political accountability – for example, by requiring the ESM Managing Director to explain and justify the design of ESM programmes to a committee of the European Parliament. Financial oversight should remain in the hands of ESM shareholders.

These proposals should be viewed as a package that largely requires joint implementation. Cutting through the ‘doom loop’ connecting banks and sovereigns in both directions requires the reduction of concentrated sovereign exposures of banks together with a European deposit insurance system. The reform of fiscal rules requires stronger and more independent fiscal watchdogs at both the national and European level. Making the no bailout rule credible requires not only a better legal framework for debt restructuring as a last resort, but also better fiscal and private risk-sharing arrangements, and an institutional strengthening of the ESM. [...]

Full analysis on VoxEU

Read Graham Bishop’s observations here


© VoxEU.org