Financial Crisis: Dealing with Systemic Risks

13 May 2008

Summary of comments by Graham Bishop to the ALDE/PSE seminar by the co-Rapporteurs on ECON’s own-initiative report on “Lamfalussy follow-up: future structure of supervision”

Disputing Ackerman of Deutsche Bank’s celebrated comments, the market will heal itself, but perhaps only up to a point. So a wise response by the public authorities should build on this natural evolution – and perhaps push it further. Open and competitive financial markets remain essential to channel the rising tide of aging Europeans’ retirement savings into productive investments around the globe.
Background
o        Size of problem: The IMF reports that $300bn of sub-prime mortgages in the US (versus $3800bn of prime) is likely to lead to $1000bn of write-offs and write-downs, though other observers such as the OECD expect the damage to be about half this level. Remarkably, nearly half the losses expected by the IMF will be borne by non-US financial firms. Problems in the EU mortgage market appear to be of a different order of severity so far – the UK’s Northern Rock had published loan loss ratios about half the level of its rivals when it ran into liquidity problems that have precipitated a dramatic review of UK bank regulatory arrangements.
o        US: So the first question to answer is how did the US system allow these “toxic” loans flow into the bottom of the financial system’s “food chain”? The working paper (WP) correctly points out that these loans had to flow through the purview of lawyers, accountants and rating agencies before reaching the investment banks that structured the products that were then purchased by investors (including the banks themselves). Apart from the initial origination of the mortgages, all the participants were subject to various forms of regulation/oversight by public authorities, especially in the US.
o        Ethics: Many of the participants at the bottom of the chain must have realised that they were exposing a significant portion of theses mortgagees to the probability of personal ruin. Correspondingly, they must have known that the probability of the projected cash-flows was debatable. As the products flowed up the chain, an increasingly highly-educated group of finance professionals should have realised the potential problems inherent in the products they were distributing. Why did their ethical values allow them to shut their eyes – at best – to this? The answers will have profound implications for their willingness to accept the letter (let alone the spirit) of any regulatory changes that ensue.
o        Remuneration: ECB President Trichet recently commented powerfully about “some financial agents’ incentives that were aligned against prudent practices”. The key problem to emerge is the lop-sided balance of risks to the banks and rewards to the executives where there is no mechanism to claw these rewards back if the products turn out not to produce the forecast flow of profits. An individual bank cannot impose new principles on its employees without risking an exodus. So public policy may need to respond – but correspondingly that can only work if applied across all major financial centres.
o        Regulators’ staffing: How can public regulators keep up with the turnover of their best staff attracted to the other side of the fence by high salaries? As the EU moves toward colleges of international supervisors for the biggest and most complex groups, the regulatory skills of the college members will be enormously valuable to the firms they regulate, so the incentives to switch sides will be tempting! Perhaps the senior regulatory staff should be on a 2-3 year contract so they know at the outset that they must stay for that period but would then be free if they wished to move.
o        Speed of legislative reaction: Commissioner McCreevy has talked of the need to avoid a “knee jerk” reaction, but has then proposed timetables for action that seem risky and based only on the timetable for the current Parliament and Commission to complete measures. The essence of the Lamfalussy Process is to consult stakeholders at the pre-legislative stage and then all the way through the process to ensure that all players accept the societal legitimacy of the resulting rules. First, that should minimise the risk of the “law of unintended consequences” emerging later. Second, it will raise the chances that ethically-minded participants will respect the spirit of the new rules, rather than just seeking to game them and by-pass the intent.
 
Specific comments
 

Euronotes Limited (trading as GrahamBishop.com)
Registered in England No. 5961447
Registered Office: Milroy House, Sayers Lane, Tenterden, Kent, TN30 6BW