The Trade and Cooperation Agreement signed between the European Union and the United Kingdom goes against six decades of UK efforts to avoid being economically disadvantaged in Europe. Tracking the evolution of the EU-UK relationship over the last 60 years can help in understanding this.
On
1 January 2021, the United Kingdom left both the European customs union
and the single market. Its trade relationship with the European Union
is now governed by a Trade and Cooperation Agreement
(TCA), which establishes a free-trade area in goods and services
broadly comparable to recent trade deals between the EU and major,
advanced non-European countries such as Canada and Japan.
To appreciate fully the significance of
this new chapter in the EU-UK trade relationship – and the ironies it
brings with it – it is useful to examine how that relationship has
evolved over the past 60-plus years. The UK is now outside structures it
helped create and that, indeed, were fundamental to UK efforts over six
decades to avoid being economically disadvantaged in Europe. It should
be noted that what follows focuses solely on trade, which is the core of
the TCA. This article does not delve into areas such as monetary
integration or the EU budget, which were important when the UK belonged
to the EU, but are marginal for the TCA.
During the 1950s, most European countries
traded with one another (and with many countries outside Europe) on
purely GATT (the General Agreements for Tariffs and Trade, created in
1947) terms, applying the same non-discriminatory MFN (most-favoured
nation) tariff to imports from all sources. This meant, for instance,
that the United Kingdom applied the same tariff on imports from France,
Sweden and any other GATT country, and that Germany applied the same
tariff on imports from France, the UK or any other GATT member.
This situation changed in 1958 with the
creation of the European Economic Community (EEC) by the original six
members, and the gradual introduction of the customs union, entailing
the abolition of duties and quotas between member states and the
establishment of a common external tariff vis-à-vis third countries.
Automatically, third countries found themselves at a disadvantage on the
EEC market, with its members now applying the common external tariff on
imports from the UK or from any other GATT member, but gradually
imposing no tariff on imports from their EEC partners.
To gain an idea of the magnitude of the
disadvantage caused by the EEC for third countries, one needs an
estimate of two factors: the size of the EEC market compared to other
markets, and how high its external tariff was. Both were relatively
large. In 1958, the EEC accounted for nearly two thirds of the GDP of Europe
(excluding Soviet bloc countries, Yugoslavia and Albania), and the
average tariff of the original six members was 13% for non-agricultural
goods and much higher for agricultural products. The loss for European
producers located outside the EEC was thus significant.
In response, the UK and six other European
countries established in 1960 the European Free Trade Association
(EFTA). Like the EEC’s customs union, this free-trade agreement (FTA)
involved the abolition of duties and quotas between its members, but,
like all other FTAs, it did not adopt a common external tariff. Instead,
each EFTA country continued to apply its own MFN schedule to imports
from third countries.
By itself, the creation of EFTA did not
eliminate the disadvantage that, for example, UK exports faced on the
German market compared to French exports after the creation of the EEC.
But it partly compensated for this loss through better market access to
other EFTA markets, such as Sweden. But the ultimate objective of the
EFTA governments was to use EFTA as a bargaining chip to negotiate duty-
and quota-free access to the EEC market in exchange for reciprocal
access to the EFTA market (in 1960 the combined GDP of the EFTA members
amounted to nearly 50% of the EEC’s GDP,
making agreement not unrealistic). This attempt failed initially and,
like producers in other countries in Europe and elsewhere, UK and other
EFTA producers had to continue trading with the EEC on relatively
disadvantageous GATT terms (Table 1, column (1)).
For the UK, the EEC’s initial refusal to
create a free-trade area with EFTA was more problematic than for any
other EFTA member. As the largest EFTA country (about 60% of EFTA GDP),
EFTA membership offered little compensation to UK exporters for the loss
of access to traditional markets now inside the EEC. In a context of
relatively poor domestic economic performance, this situation prompted
the UK government to submit a first application to join the EEC in 1961.
It was rejected in 1963, triggering a second UK application in 1967
that was again rejected. Finally, the UK joined the EU in 1973 after the
departure from office of the main stumbling block, French President de
Gaulle.
This marked the beginning of the second
chapter in the relationship between the EEC and the UK. The UK’s
accession to the EEC had two ripple effects for other EFTA members and
for Ireland, all of which were highly dependent on access to the UK
market. The first consequence was the accession, also in 1973, of
Denmark and Ireland to the EEC (Norway voted on it, but decided
against). The second was the creation of a free-trade area between the
EEC’s customs union and the remaining EFTA members, which now also
included Iceland. Since the EEC had already established FTAs with
Greece, Spain and Turkey, it meant that, by 1973, EEC trade with
European countries (excluding socialist countries) was mostly duty- and
quota-free (Table 1, column (2)). The accession of Greece to the EEC in
1981 barely changed the situation (Table 1, columns (3)).
The third chapter in the UK-EEC
relationship opened in 1985 and closed in 2004. The EEC – joined by
Portugal and Spain in 1986 (Table 1, column (4)) – and its custom union
had been highly successful in abolishing tariffs and quotas among its
members. But it had done nothing to remove non-border measures, such as
product conformity procedures, that continued to hamper trade in goods.
Nor had it removed barriers to trade in services or the free circulation
of capital and labour. This task fell to the Delors Commission
and one of its two British members, Lord Cockfield, sent to Brussels by
Prime Minister Margaret Thatcher to eliminate bureaucratic barriers to
trade within the EEC. Cockfield’s 1985 White Paper on ‘Completing the
Internal Market’ and the accompanying 1986 Single European Act formed
the foundations of the single market, as the common market was then
renamed.
The central role of Thatcher and Cockfield in the creation of the single market is well known. Martin Sandbu has even suggested in the Financial Times (30 December 2020) that “Thatcher
was the political force behind a genuinely unified European market for
goods, services, labour and capital; Arthur Cockfield …was its
intellectual architect and bureaucratic engineer”. The creation of
the single market in 1993 didn’t just boost trade and growth for the 12
EEC members (column (5) in Table 1). As argued by Baldwin (1995) and verified statistically by Sapir (2001), the single market programme also produced a “domino effect” for EEC neighbours, whose access to the EEC market was threatened by its closer integration.
In the space of three years, five EFTA
countries requested EEC accession: Austria (1989), Sweden (1991), and
Finland, Norway and Switzerland (1992). Austria, Finland and Sweden
ultimately joined in 1995 the European Union, the successor of the EEC
founded in 1993. Meanwhile, Norway (whose citizens had rejected EU
membership), Iceland and Liechtenstein joined the newly formed European
Economic Area (EEA), giving them access to the EU’s single market on
terms equal to those of EU members. Switzerland, whose citizens rejected
accession to both the EU and the EEA, also gained access to the EU’s
single market, though on less equal terms than EEA members. Turkey,
which had applied for EEC membership in 1987 but was only declared
eligible to join the EU in 1997, upgraded its FTA with the EU to a
customs union in 1995. Finally, the former socialist countries of
central and eastern Europe established FTAs with the EU.
By 1995, the EU counted 15 members. Nearly
all other European countries had close economic ties with the EU,
trading with it on better than World Trade Organisation (the successor
to GATT, established in 1995) terms, a situation partly linked to the
UK’s decisions to join the EEC in 1973 and to help create the single
market two decades later (Table 1, column (6)).
The fourth chapter in the UK-EU trade
relationship came with the EU accession of eleven former socialist
countries of central and eastern Europe, plus Cyprus and Malta, two
former British colonies, starting in 2004. This fourth wave of EU
enlargement, which was strongly supported by the UK, created the biggest
customs union and single market in the world, made up of the 28 EU
members, the only countries belonging to both the European customs union
and single market. Turkey also belonged to the customs union, but not
to the single market; three of the EFTA members (Iceland, Liechtenstein,
and Norway) belonged to the single market, but not the customs union;
and the fourth EFTA member, Switzerland, belonged to large parts of the
single market, but not the customs union (Table 1, column (7)).
This situation has now been modified
profoundly by the decision of the UK to leave the EU and to leave both
the European customs union and the single market. The UK-EU trade
relationship is now governed by the TCA, which is fairly similar to the
FTAs between the EU and major, advanced non-European countries, such as
Canada (the Comprehensive Trade and Economic Agreement, CETA) and Japan
(the EU-Japan Economic Partnership Agreement, EUJEPA). These agreements
also provide preferential access for trade in goods, though not
completely duty- and quota-free as the TCA does, a difference which,
together with the difference in geographical proximity, explains why
only the TCA includes level-playing-field conditions. Like the TCA, the
agreements with Canada and Japan also provide some preferential access
for trade in services and the removal of some non-border barriers to
trade in goods and services, but considerably less so than within the
single market.
Hence, the UK now finds itself in a trade
relationship with the EU on terms that are far less favourable than
those enjoyed by EU members or other EU neighbours like Norway or
Switzerland, which enjoy duty- and quota-free access to the EU market
for goods, and full or significant access to the EU single market for
goods, services, capital and labour. The TCA’s terms are also less
favourable than those of Turkey for trade in goods (since rules of
origin are absent in the customs union but not in the TCA), though they
are better for services (since the EU-Turkey customs union does not
cover services; Table 1, column (8)).
The UK’s decision to leave the European customs union and single market is doubly ironic.
The first irony is that this decision is
indirectly related to the single market programme and the fourth
enlargement, two EU policies spearheaded by successive UK governments.
The single market birthed the single currency in which the UK refused to
participate and which left it frustrated at being excluded from
important decisions, especially during the euro area sovereign debt
crisis, as Ivan Rogers,
a former UK ambassador to the EU has vividly explained. Moreover, the
single market in conjunction with the eastern enlargement brought large
inflows of foreign workers to the UK who were initially welcomed but
eventually generated a backlash because of perceived pressure on certain
public services.
The second irony is that the decision runs
completely counter to the UK’s efforts during the past 60 years to
avoid being economically disadvantaged in Europe, starting with its
decision to create EFTA in 1960. Today, the UK finds itself outside the
EU and with less favourable access to its market than any other European
country. All its former EFTA companions have either joined the EU, or
remain outside the EU but inside the European single market. True, by
staying outside the EU, the UK will be free to set its own rules, but it
will have to continue to adhere to EU rules in order to retain access
to the EU market, which combines size and geographical proximity like no
other market in the world. The future will tell whether this fifth
chapter in the UK-EU trade relationship is temporary or lasting, and
what the short-, medium- and long-term consequences will be.
Recommended citation:
Sapir, A. (2021) ‘The double irony of the new UK-EU trade relationship’, Bruegel Blog, 12 January
Republishing and referencing
Bruegel considers itself a public good and
takes no institutional standpoint. Anyone is free to republish and/or
quote this post without prior consent. Please provide a full reference,
clearly stating Bruegel and the relevant author as the source, and
include a prominent hyperlink to the original post.
Read entire article Bruegel
© Bruegel